Skip to main content
  • Original article
  • Open access
  • Published:

An empirical inquiry into the determinants of public education spending in Europe

Abstract

This paper makes two important contributions. Firstly, it uncovers some of the main economic determinants driving the dynamics of public education spending in Europe. Drawing mainly on the insights provided by Baumol’s cost theory, the baseline specification uses unit labour costs and real GDP per capita as its main determinants. Some important institutional rigidities are also highlighted. The results confirm the fast relative increase in education costs, exposing the long-term affordability challenge of public education investment. Secondly, by including a policy objective and translating the empirical specification into a decision rule, the paper touches on some less mentioned determinants, such as policy commitment. Unfortunately, there is only weak overall evidence that public education spending would increase in response to a lack of progress in the policy objective. Finally, policy implications are discussed.

JEL: D78, H41, H52, I22

1 Introduction

The sustained rise in the relative cost of certain public services continues to be a major source of concern for societies and governments alike. The problem has been first observed and discussed in Baumol and Bowen (1966) and Baumol (1967), with sectors such as education and health-care being given as prominent examples. Baumol (2012) further explains that the pain experienced by a society seems to be caused mainly by the relative dynamics of these costs rather than their levels (see also Wolff et al., 2014). In fact, this problem has been so pervasive across both the developed and the developing world, and over the last couple of decades, that it has been commonly labeled as the (Baumol’s) ‘cost disease’. Obviously, such a persistent and widespread phenomenon must have roots that go deeper than country-specific characteristics and institutional arrangements.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Sensitivity check of model coefficients when one country is removed from the sample

I start from these considerations when empirically analysing a panel dataset that spans over the 2000–2012 time period and refers to current European Union (EU) member states. In this data environment, I intend to highlight some common determinants driving the dynamics of public education spending and to draw insights with respect to their policy importance. I also focus on spending dynamics rather than levels since this allows me to address some large heterogeneity concerns in my sample. I construct an empirical specification building on theoretical insights borrowed mainly from Baumol (1967) ‘cost model’, but also from Bowen (1980) ‘revenue theory of costs’. Using just aggregate measures of unit labour costs and income per capita, I am able to capture the sustained rise in education costs (and therefore spending), despite the inertia observed in classroom ‘production technology’ (measured by student-teacher ratios). Relevant studies employing similar approaches to model education spending can be found in Fernandez and Rogerson (2001), Gundlach et al. (2001), Archibald and Feldman (2008), Wolff et al. (2014), Chen and Moul (2014). In general, their findings largely confirm the theoretical underpinnings discussed above. In fact, the Baumol’s cost theory in particular has been an excellent workhorse for empirical investigations in many closely-related areas, such as health-care, general services, and other labour-intensive activities.

The paper also touches on some less mentioned determinants of education spending that bear more with political economy considerations, such as policy commitment. Here, I discuss commitment with a focus on public education spending (at primary, secondary and tertiary levels), although extensions to other policy areas (e.g., employment and social security) remain possible within the same methodological approach. The understanding is that, beyond theoretical determinants and inherent institutional rigidities, there will always be some degree of policy discretion (as opposed to time-consistent policy rules that define commitment) that would amend funding allocations due to some specific considerations. As a prerequisite to evaluating policy commitment, I expand my empirical specification to include a policy-relevant education objective and attempt to establish a link between the progress registered in this objective and the dynamics of spending (which I take to be the policy instrument). Lisbon strategy (or Europe 2010) together with its current, more detailed, Europe 2020 version were designed to promote education attainment and social cohesion, raise employment and foster innovation along with other long-term policy objectives.Footnote 1 Hence, I draw on these two policy agendas in search of some well-defined, consistent indicators to serve as policy objectives for my analysis. With respect to education, there is only one clear and measureable policy objective mentioned in both strategies: reducing the share of early school leavers (henceforth ESL), i.e., 18–24 year-olds with less than upper secondary educational attainment who are no longer in education or training —according to the definition of the European Commission.Footnote 2 In this context, I investigate whether EU governments have shown determination in their pursuit for better education goals, i.e., lower ESL shares; for a positive characterization of policy commitment, I expect public education spending to increase whenever there is a lack of or insufficient progress with respect to the ESL policy objective.Footnote 3

The paper makes at least two important contributions. Firstly, it empirically identifies some of the main common determinants driving the dynamics of public education spending in Europe, building on some well-established economic theories. The paper provides clear evidence that the annual growth rate in public education spending (especially at primary and secondary levels) has considerably exceeded the annual growth rate in unit labour costs—a preferred measure for portraying the Baumol ‘cost disease’ and an indicator of general price trends. Unfortunately, this finding also exposes the long-term affordability challenge of public education investment. A system of seemingly unrelated regression equations is proposed to account for any possible substitutions or complementarities between different education levels. Moreover, by broadening the perspective, I show that the dynamics of total government spending per capita can also be easily described by relying on the same major determinants as in the case of education spending per student (a recent empirical review on public spending determinants can be found in Shelton, 2007). In addition, the paper highlights some dimensions where institutional rigidities are higher and can, therefore, generate highly persistent dynamics in public education spending (e.g., student-teacher ratio, spending share of teachers’ wages).

Secondly, the paper attempts to empirically evaluate the link between education spending and education attainment, where the latter is defined in terms of early school leavers—a highly relevant policy objective according to the strategies promoted by the EU. In establishing such a link between the two elements, the analysis touches on the issue of policy commitment to education. Commitment here implies a very clear sequencing of the decision-making process: spending is adjusted or decided with respect to previous/past realized performances in the policy objective. Unfortunately, I am not able to find sufficiently strong evidence that policy commitment has been a major determinant of education spending across EU states, although this finding is clearly dependent on the specific approach adopted here.

This analysis also has implications for other closely-related strands of research. On the one hand, education is known to foster technical progress and productivity growth that, in turn, provide not only resources to fund more education but also the right incentives to inspire better education choices for the young generations.Footnote 4 The possibility of such a virtuous circle highlights the importance of education investment due to its favourable consequences on several socio-economic dimensions, including better career prospects, faster transition from school to work, and higher social mobility. On the other hand, education usually represents a small allocation in total government spending, much smaller than other, more pressing, policy objectives such as employment and social security. In fact, short-term political considerations might dominate the public budgeting process today, especially given the high and persistent unemployment levels in Europe. However, if education costs were to continue rising faster than general prices, the governments would be forced into a difficult trade-off between the long-term affordability and provision of public education and the short-term political considerations arising from more pressing objectives.Footnote 5 In the end, although the cost disease ‘turns out to affect only the way we divide the money we spend’ (see Wolff et al., 2014, p. 19), this might not be too comforting for governments that need to deliver on seemingly conflicting policy objectives.

The paper is organized as following. Section 2 discusses the theoretical foundations of the paper. The data and the main empirical specifications of the model are presented in section 3. Section 4 discusses the empirical results and their policy implications. Finally, section 5 concludes.

2 Theoretical framework

As a theoretical basis for this modelling exercise, I draw mainly on two well-established economic theories. The first theoretical strand rests on the seminal work of Baumol and Bowen (1966) and Baumol (1967), who propose an ‘unbalanced growth’ model to explain the dynamics of an economy consisting of two sectors: a ‘progressive’ one, and an ‘un-progressive’ or ‘stagnant’ one. The second theoretical strand relies on Bowen (1980) and his ‘revenue theory of costs’ formulated in relation to higher education.

The main assumption behind the first theoretical approach is that labour productivity grows in the long-term only in the ‘progressive’ sector, which is usually identified with the manufacturing or, more generally, with the good-providing sector. Beyond the undisputed statistical evidence, several arguments can be put forward to support the claim that manufacturing is more likely to enjoy higher levels of productivity growth over the long-term. Labour productivity, defined as output per worker, generally grows as a result of technological progress and innovation, increased capital per worker, economies of scale, etc. Being highly exposed to international competition, the manufacturing sector is forced to innovate to retain competitiveness. A second argument is that new technologies can more easily be incorporated into physical capital and equipment,Footnote 6 and the manufacturing sector is known to be more capital-intensive than other sectors. Lastly, economies of scale are more easily observed in the case of good-producing industries that can benefit from the automatization of routine tasks. When identifying ‘non-progressive’ sectors, Baumol cites education and health-care as two highly labour-intensive sectors, where labour productivity does not generally grow in the long-run. The basic idea is that labour-intensive industries cannot use technology as a leverage to increase productivity as much as capital-intensive industries do. However, nominal wages in both sectors grow at the same rate over the long-term, mainly because the two sectors are competing for the same pool of workers.Footnote 7 Due to long-term nominal wage convergence between the two sectors, lagging productivity growth in the non-progressive sector will put upward pressure on the relative costs in that sector.Footnote 8 Baumol assumes that both sectors produce final goods and services (i.e., no intermediate products) according to the following production functions:

$$ \begin{array}{l}{Y}_t^{man}=a*{L}_t^{man}* \exp (rt)\\ {}{Y}_t^{edu}=b*{L}_t^{edu},\end{array} $$

where man is an index for the ‘progressive’ sector and edu is the index for the ‘stagnant’ sector, Y denotes the real output, L is the labour input and a,b are constants. Notice that the progressive sector grows at the exogenously given rate r, which is the growth rate of the technological progress.

The nominal wages in the two sectors grow at the same rate as the technological progress, i.e., W t  = W * exp(rt). Consequently, a prediction of this theory is that the relative cost per unit of output goes to infinity, i.e., \( \left(\frac{W_t*{L}_t^{edu}}{Y_t^{edu}}\right)/\left(\frac{W_t*{L}_t^{man}}{Y_t^{man}}\right)=a/b* \exp (rt)\underset{t\to \infty }{\to}\infty, \) implying that the ‘stagnant’ sector might vanish in the long-run. In fact, depending on demand elasticity, customers might not tolerate an ‘infinite’ price increase, and therefore some products might even disappear from the market or retreat to luxury niches (Baumol cites expensive restaurants or famous theaters as relevant examples). However, in the case of necessities such as education or health-care, price elasticity is very low, and therefore higher costs will be passed-through into higher prices, causing an ‘unbalanced-growth’ dynamics between the two sectors in nominal terms.

Baumol imagines two extreme scenarios. The first scenario assumes that the relative output (or consumption) of the two sectors, i.e., \( {Y}_t^{man}/{Y}_t^{edu}, \) is to remain constant in real terms. Under the constraint that labour supply is fixed and given by \( L={L}_t={L}_t^{man}+{L}_t^{edu}, \) this additional assumption would imply that the labour share of the ‘non-progressive’ sector will constantly grow over time, such that \( {L}_{t=\infty}^{edu}={L}_{t=\infty }. \) Since wages tend to converge in the two sectors, this also implies that the relative expenditure share of the stagnant sector will keep rising indefinitely (in nominal terms). The second scenario is just the reverse of the previous one: assuming that relative expenditures in the two sectors stay constant in the long-term, the consequences are that the relative output will grow in the ‘progressive’ sector, but its employment share will remain constant. In reality, because of the uneven dynamics of productivity and wages in the two sectors, the share of expenditures allocated to the non-progressive sector will raise over time—something that has been coined in the literature as the (Baumol’s) ‘cost disease’.

Despite some inherent critiques, this modelling setting has been a fruitful avenue of research in the literature analysing the dynamics of the education sector (see Gundlach et al. 2001; Archibald and Feldman, 2008; Wolff et al., 2014; Chen and Moul, 2014), the health-care sector (see Hartwig, 2008; 2011), and the more general service-providing sector (see Sasaki, 2007; Nordhaus, 2008). Recently, Baumol (2012) appears to favour an alternative explanation of his theory where the ‘cost disease’ might be more of a ‘cost utopia’ if higher costs in the non-progressive sector are simply driven by higher demand (in contrast to the more supply-side determinants outlined in the original theory), which in turn is supported by the higher income generated in the progressive sector (Chen and Moul, 2014).

Probably not far from this alternative interpretation provided by Baumol (2012), the second relevant literature strand rests on Bowen (1980) and his insights with respect to drivers of education costs, in particular, higher education costs. Bowen argues that available revenues are the only constraint on how much to spend on education. In his view, schools maximize ‘education excellence, prestige and influence’, only facing a revenue constraint. To provide and empirical support for his theory, Bowel points at both the increase in disposable income and the increase in education costs experienced by the developed countries over the last decades (see also Kane, 1999; Fernandez and Rogerson, 2001; Archibald and Feldman, 2008). It should be noted however that this second explanation of raising education cost looks less appealing from a theoretical perspective, resting mainly on available empirical evidence at that time.

In addition, one may consider the political economy models that regard the preferences of the median voter (see Fernandez and Rogerson, 1995, 1996, 1998; Gradstein and Justman, 1997; Gradstein, 2000; Easterly, 2001; Benabou 1996; 2002). According to these models, households’ income distribution play a key role in the public support for education, mainly because inequality with respect to education opportunities could be mitigated through fiscal policy means (e.g., taxes, transfers). The median voter would be willing to support the public budget through paid taxes, and as a consequence, the dynamics of public education costs over time will be a direct function of voters’ disposable income. While I do not specifically attempt to estimate such models here, their insights might be useful to frame the policy discussion later, especially with respect to affordability of public education and policy trade-offs.

3 Empirical strategy

3.1 Data

The main data source on education spending is Eurostat, i.e., the government finance statistics section (COFOG, based on the ESA95 standard), and covers the time period 2000–2012. This source contains only general government spending for all major public domains, including education; due to its limited coverage, it excludes other important sources of funding for education, especially private sources (e.g., funding provided by households), but also foreign sources (e.g., funding by international organizations). I also use data on education drawn from the OECD/UNESCO/Eurostat joint data collection and covering the time period 2000–2012. The data is organized according to the International Standard Classification System of Education or ISCED (on a scale from 0 to 6) developed by UNESCO in 1997. In addition, all other relevant macroeconomic indicators used in the empirical section are taken from the European Commission AMECO database (downloaded in January-February 2015) maintained by DG ECFIN. As a general remark, however, the resulting panel is slightly unbalanced due to data availability issues, with longer time-series available especially for older EU members.

In empirical studies comparing variables and indicators (in levels) across countries, there seems to be a widespread agreement to use purchasing power parities (the PPS standard). However, as discussed in the introduction, in order to better address the policy implications and concerns with respect to the long-term affordability of rising education costs, I focus on the dynamics of spending (see Baumol, 2012; Wolff et al., 2014). Therefore, all the variables employed in this paper are in (log) first-differences.Footnote 9 I provide three more (technical) reasons for such a choice: (i) avoid potential non-stationarity issues in the empirical estimation, (ii) reduce the influence of some methodological breaks in the available time-series, and (iii) mitigate the impact of time-invariant country-specific factors that dominate the education spending data in levels, reflecting cultural, historical and political differences.

Using data in first-differences also allows me to avoid any potential pitfalls with respect to a lack of empirical evidence on the causality link between education outcomes and financial resources/spending, as extensively discussed in Hanushek (2003). In his influential study, Hanushek advocates for the need to improve school and teacher’s characteristics rather than to increase spending.Footnote 10 Specifically, he highlights factors that would mostly reflect country/school-specific characteristics, including autonomy over curriculum, accountability, teacher’s knowledge of the subject, etc. These indicators do not have adequate time-variation to be considered relevant for my modelling purposes (e.g., PISA surveys conducted by the OECD every 3 years are not easily comparable over time). Public education spending, however, is part of a policy decision-making process and subject to public scrutiny on a much more frequent basis, in contrast to other structural policies that might address the qualitative aspects discussed above. Accordingly, the approach presented in this paper can be considered to account for these qualitative factors but in a rather uninformative way, i.e., by using data in first-differences.

OECD recommends using data expressed in national prices as there is no need to convert variables in PPS and, thus, introduce additional variability caused by relative price movements (see Ahmad et al., 2003). I will follow this advice in my empirical analysis, which is presented in the next sections.

3.2 Model specification

The specification of the model describing the dynamics of public education spending is built in three steps.

In a first step, I draw on the theoretical insights provided in the previous section and set up a ‘baseline’ model specification using only the main economic indicators highlighted in section 2 and denoted here by economicI. I follow a rich empirical literature taking an empirical perspective on the Baumol’s theoretical model (see Gundlach et al., 2001; Hartwig, 2008, 2011). Accordingly, the annual change in the ‘non-progressive’ sector’s expenditures is modelled as a function of changes in unit labour costs (ULC)—simply computed as nominal wages over labour productivity. While some authors have used sector-specific variables,Footnote 11 the lack of available time-series does not allow me to follow this route. Instead, I use the aggregate indicators, corresponding to the whole economy, much as in Hartwig (2008, 2011), where a similar approach is used to investigate health-care spending.

Besides ULC, I include real GDP per capita, which I take as the main economic determinant according the second theoretical strand that relies on the Bowen (1980) and his ‘revenue theory of cost’. As noted by Archibald and Feldman (2008), the analytical framework formulated by Bowen is less appealing because it lacks clear theoretical foundations. However, GDP per capita is one of the most used indicators in empirical studies on education and is an excellent candidate to control for any remaining heterogeneity.Footnote 12 Moreover, the GDP per capita would also adequately control for demand-side effects, where higher income generates higher demand for education services. A stylized version of the ‘baseline’ model specification is given below:

$$ \Delta spendin{g}_{i,t}=f\left(\Delta economic{I}_{i,t}\right)=f\left(\Delta UL{C}_{i,t},\ \Delta GDPperca{p}_{i,t}\right) $$
(1)

where spending denotes the amount of public funding devoted to education, ∆ denotes the log-first difference of the indicator and f is a general functional form specification. The subscript t is a time index, while i is a country index, both common notations in a panel setting.

In a second step, I enrich the ‘baseline’ model specification to include additional controls. These controls are supposed to reflect the large heterogeneity existing in education systems across the EU in terms of how they are organized, what are the most important institutional rigidities, and other relevant dimensions. Beyond organizational aspects, education spending can be ultimately related to the number of teachers and students, classes and schools; in the short-run these figures cannot be easily changed, thus, worsening institutional rigidities. Teachers are the most important resource in the production of education and their wage bill represents the biggest single contributor to total public education spending. The relative inertia in classroom ‘production technology’ implies that student-teacher ratios are highly persistent too. In addition, any foreseen changes in the quantity/quality of existing infrastructure (schools and/or classes) are part of a multi-annual planning process and will be reflected in persistent capital expenditures, which represent the third most important contributor to total public education spending.Footnote 13

Moreover, my list of potential controls is severely limited by data availability on a yearly basis. In line with the discussion above, I use the following indicators: the share of teachers’ wages in current education spending, the share of capital expenditure in total education spending, class size and student-teacher ratios.Footnote 14 The additional controls introduced at this step are generally denoted as structureI. I formulate my model as in (2) and label this the ‘extended’ model specification:

$$ \Delta\;spendin{g}_{i,t}=f\left(\Delta\;economic{I}_{i,t},\kern0.37em \Delta\;structure{I}_{i,t-1}\right) $$
(2)

The one year lag assumed for the indicators reflecting the structure of education spending captures the inherent persistency in its dynamics. It can be easily argued that the number of available teachers and number of classes and schools do not significantly change over the timeframe of 1 year (at least not in a regular way that can be captured in a typical time-series regression analysis). However, over a longer timeframe these indicators will eventually change for different reasoning: demographics dynamics, policy considerations, etc., and therefore the need to control for their influence.

As a third and final step, I include the registered progress in the education policy objective as an additional regressor. This would establish a direct link between the dynamics of education spending (which can be seen as the policy instrument) and the movements in the policy objective, allowing thus an empirical characterization of the policy commitment. As discussed in the introduction of the paper, I consider that the relevant policy objective consists in reducing the share of early school leavers. The most general formulation of the empirical model in its ‘full’ specification is given below:

$$ \Delta \kern0.28em spendin{g}_{i,t}=f\left(\Delta \kern0.28em economic{I}_{i,t},\kern0.28em \Delta \kern0.28em structure{I}_{i,t-1},\kern0.28em \Delta \kern0.28em objective{I}_{i,t-1}\right), $$
(3)

where ∆ objectiveI denotes the progress registered in the policy objective and its 1 year lag is required to expose the policy decision rule consistent with commitment to education. In my empirical setting, commitment implies a very particular sequencing of the decision-making process: the instrument is adjusted only after observing the progress registered in the policy objective.Footnote 15 The 1 year lag might be simply justified by data availability: spending decisions are taken with a forward-looking perspective, but are based on readily available statistical data, which usually refer to some previous period (higher lag orders might be needed if the time gap in data availability is assumed to be longer).

I adopt a system-estimation approach meaning that, for each main education level, I specify an equation describing the dynamics of spending at that particular level, i.e., primary (including pre-primary), secondary and tertiary; accordingly, the corresponding groupings based on the ISCED classification will be: ISCED 0–1, or ISCED 2–4, and ISCED 5–6, respectively. Latter, I will include a fourth equation describing the dynamics of total public spending as a way to acknowledge the existing budget constraints. I estimate the system using seemingly-unrelated regression methods (SUR) to get un-biased and efficient estimates of the coefficients. There are two main arguments that support the system-estimation approach. The first argument rests on the characteristics of the policy decision-making process in public finance, i.e., all decisions are interrelated and simultaneous. A second argument is that all the estimated equations will include at least one common regressor, i.e., ULCs and, eventually, GDP per capita. The inherent assumption behind a SUR estimation method is that the residuals of the individual regressions included in the system are all correlated (i.e., not independent). Accordingly, I always report the Breusch-Pagan test of independence in my results: a rejection of the null (i.e., independence) means that the SUR method is appropriate for estimating the model.

All the data used in the estimation is in nominal terms, local currency, per pupil/student, and expressed in full time equivalents (FTE).Footnote 16 The use of spending per pupil/student adequately captures all relevant demographic dynamics; accordingly, the model does not need to include demographics as a separate regressor, thus, saving valuable degrees of freedom in the estimation. A similar argument can be made with respect to the fourth equation, which specifies the dynamics of total public spending in per capita terms.

4 Empirical results

4.1 A three-equation system

The first thing that needs to be checked is whether the theoretical framework discussed in section 2 is validated by the data. Indeed, for all ‘baseline’ and ‘extended’ specifications presented in Table 1 below, the coefficient of the unit labour cost, i.e., the wage-productivity differential or simply the ‘Baumol’ variable, is always significant in all three equations of the system. Moreover, the constant term is also highly significant, especially at primary and secondary levels (for tertiary education the results are more mixed since the constant term is not always statistically significant). This finding confirms the faster rise in education costs relative to the rise in ULCs—a common proxy for capturing broad inflationary pressures in (most new-Keynesian) economic models. It also reveals the most often advocated solution to the ‘cost disease’ problem: since only wage growth in excess of productivity gains would be fed into higher education costs. This suggests productivity growth as a possible long-term remedy (see Wolff et al., 2014).

Table 1 Estimates for public education spending per (FTE) student

When comparing the ‘baseline’ with the ‘extended’ specification, however, there appears to be a drop in the estimated ‘Baumol’ coefficient. The drop seems substantial in the case of pre- and primary (ISCED 0–1) and tertiary education levels (ISCED 5–6), but it must be associated with the introduction of the (lagged) share of teachers’ wages as an additional control in the regression.Footnote 17 This suggests that the share of teachers’ wages is an important determinant—an additional nominal driver of public education costs, though certainly carrying a different content than the ‘Baumol cost’ variable.Footnote 18 The ‘extended’ specification includes the additional controls discussed in section 3.2. For the specifications reported here, I use student/teacher ratios instead of class size due to better data availability. The pupil/teacher ratio (only averages over aggregated ISCED 1–3 levels are available from Eurostat) is highly significant and the estimated coefficients are all negative, pointing at the relevance of this indicator for cost analysis.

Adding real GDP per capita as an additional regressor to either ‘baseline’ or ‘extended’ specifications does not significantly change the estimated coefficients for ULCs. However, it does improve the overall fit of the model (i.e., the R2 increases when adding GDP per capita). As evidenced in Table 1, adding GDP per capita seems no more than a better way to control for some remaining country-specific factors (probably not entirely removed after first-differentiating the data). Indeed, the specification illustrated in column (5) replaces the GDP per capita with country-specific dummies, which deliver an expected improvement in the overall fit of the model. However, the specification with GDP per capita is preferred by the Akaike (AIC) and Bayesian Information Criterion (BIC), with both being larger in the ‘extended & country dummies’ compared to ‘extended & GDP per capita’.

Section 2 has provided an extensive discussion on the relevant mechanisms behind the dynamics of education spending; yet, these theoretical mechanisms are assumed to work mainly over the long-term. When exploring data with an annual frequency, richer dynamics might be revealed. I rely on the empirical literature to provide some needed guidelines in my investigation. Humphreys (2000) and Delaney and Doyle (2011) among many others find strong evidence that business cycles affect government financial support for higher education. Although primary and secondary education are compulsory and, therefore, should not be too much subject to short-term policy considerations, I will include ‘output gap’ as an additional regressor (i.e., proxy for business cycle) for all levels of education considered. However, I had to remove GDP per capita from this specification (depicted in column (6) in Table 1) to avoid colinearity due to the high correlation between the two indicators; it is interesting to observe that the Baumol coefficient drops significantly or even losses statistical significance in some cases. This finding points to the fact that the output gap and the ULC might both reflect similar information, such as the gap between demand (proxied by the wage component of the ULC) and supply (proxied by the productivity component of the ULC).

To select the most parsimonious specification, I rely again on AIC and BIC information criteria. In this case, both parsimony measures (AIC and BIC) prefer the specification that includes GDP per capita (column 4) to the one that includes output gap (column 6).

4.2 A four-equation system

Within the broader context of public budgeting, education spending represents only a minor allocation of public financial resources. According to Eurostat, at the aggregate level of the European Union (EU), education makes up for a little bit more than 10% of total government spending. Over the 2000–2012 period this percentage has varied significantly across EU member states, from a minimum of 6% in Greece to a maximum of 19% in Estonia. Given this allocation problem, there is a need to account for the existing general public budget constraints when modelling the dynamics of education spending. The Appendix discusses some additional reasons to append a fourth equation to the initial three-equation system.

To address this aspect, specification (7) in Table 2 below presents a four-equation system, where the forth equation describes the dynamics of the general public spending per capita. The initial three-equation system has already addressed the possibility of reallocations (through correlations) between the three relevant education levels: primary, secondary and tertiary. Now, within a four-equation system, the possibility of reallocation between education and other areas of the public budget is also addressed (e.g., spending on economic affairs, military and defense are all substitutes to public education spending, etc.).

Table 2 Estimates for public education spending per (FTE) student

The empirical specification of this fourth equation is intentionally kept simple. Baumol’s theory can be easily extended to include all publicly-provided services (same assumptions are needed), while income per capita is one of the most relevant determinants for general government spending (see Shelton, 2007). Accordingly, the same two theoretical determinants outlined in the previous sections are included. The coefficients of the first three equations of the system remain basically unchanged between specifications (4) and (7). Interestingly, the fourth equation has a higher explanatory power than the other three, despite relying on just two determinants and a constant term; the constant is statistically significant, though smaller in absolute value than in the case of primary and secondary levels. Other advantages pertaining to specification (7) over specification (4) are highlighted in the Appendix.

Despite all the existing budgetary constraints, some of them arising from the strict EU institutional governance framework, there has always been some degree of domestic policy discretion that could change a given spending allocation due to specific considerations. I intend to reflect the commitment idea using the ‘full’ model specification, which is portrayed by equation (3) from section 3.2. I am making the implicit assumption that policy commitment implies a very clear sequencing of the decision-making process: current changes in spending allocation to education are decided based on past performances. Compared to the ‘extended’ specification, I now include an additional regressor in each of the three initial equations of the system. In principle, lagged changes in the policy objective (or similar transformations thereof – see below) should represent relevant measures of past performances. Given the definition of the policy objective,Footnote 19 a rising share of early school leavers would reflect a worsening of the situation, while declining ESL shares reflect an improvement (i.e., the lower the ESL shares, the better). Accordingly, a truly committed policy-maker would increase spending today (and possibly over the next periods) to counterbalance any unfavourable past developments in the ESL objective. Similarly, a policy-maker could be allowed to reduce spending today if past ESL progress is considered as satisfactory.Footnote 20

In reality, different EU countries could make different spending allocations despite registering a similar ESL progress; likewise, countries could behave similarly (i.e., increase/decrease education spending by the same percent) despite witnessing very different ESL developments. Given the large diversity in ESL performancesFootnote 21 across the EU members, there is a need to introduce some relevant benchmarks or reference values in order to adequately evaluate/measure the progress registered in the policy objective for a given country. Despite some inherent simplifications, I present three ways to achieve this goal and illustrate the results in Table 3 below, namely in specifications (8), (9) and (10).

Table 3 Estimates for public education spending per (FTE) student with policy commitment
  • Firstly, I use the lagged change in ESL as the easiest way to include a feedback mechanism into my specification, which states the policy decision rule dictating how current spending is adjusted. This specification corresponds to column (8) in Table 3 below and is labelled as ‘own lag’ because progress in the ESL objective is measured against its own lag. The intuition is that a policy-maker would compare the available (t-1) ESL value with its previous, (t-2), ESL value to quantify progress before deciding on education spending for the current time period, t. Consequently, the additional regressor included in specification (8) is given by: ∆log(ESL)t-1 or, equivalently, by the difference defined in ESL levels: log(ESL)t-1 – log(ESL)t-2.

  • Secondly, for specification (9) in Table 3, I consider that the policy-maker evaluates the available (t-1) ESL value against a fixed (time-invariant) unobserved country-specific reference value. Such a reference value could be either a fixed target or an optimal determined ESL value, though here I include dummy variables to balance the lack of such country-specific measures over the whole estimation period.Footnote 22 This specification, which I label as ‘FE’, also controls for any remaining cross-sectional heterogeneity not accounted for so far by the ‘full’ model specification. Consequently, I include log(ESL)t-1 as an additional regressor along with a country-specific dummy.

  • Thirdly, I consider that, for a given country, the relevant reference value to measure the progress registered by its ESL objective is the EU-aggregate ESL value. This specification, labelled as ‘EU27’, corresponds to column (10) in Table 3. Consequently, the regressor included in the model is given by the difference between the country-specific ESL and the EU27Footnote 23 average ESL, i.e., log(ESL)t-1 – log(ESLEU27)t-1.

In practice, it is more likely that policy-makers rely on a series of benchmarks and reference values (possibly including the ones employed above, i.e., own lags, specific targets, EU averages etc.) to evaluate their progress and decide spending allocations in education. Based on the results displayed in Table 3, there is some weak statistical evidence of policy commitment in specification (9), where dummies were introduced as a proxy for fixed ESL targets. This evidence should be understood within the limits of the approach considered here. Interestingly, in model (9) the coefficient associated with the commitment proxy is positive for primary education but negative for tertiary education, meaning that, for example, if previous ESL values were above a fixed (country-specific) reference value, spending would increase at the primary (including pre-primary) but decrease at the tertiary education level – a result that makes sense given that the policy objective is expressed in terms of school dropouts with less than (upper) secondary education. Unfortunately, such weak statistical evidence does not allow me to draw strong conclusions with respect to policy commitment in this empirical setting. The explanation could be related to large data heterogeneity issues, most likely due to the presence of some gross outliers in the sample (see Appendix) or simply because the model tries to pool together countries with very different policy attitudes. Empirical results were sensitive to sample length changes, i.e., dropping more than one observation either from the beginning or from the end of the sample would alter the coefficients and their statistical significance; a future investigation that could leverage on better data availability and span over longer time periods should perhaps come with more insights and more robust findings. Probably more interesting, the results were not that sensitive when dropping some of the selected controls that define the ‘extended’ specification.

4.3 Policy discussion

With public education costs growing faster than aggregate prices, affordability concerns inevitably arise in any discussion on public education investment. The empirical results above have exposed the ‘cost disease’ as a common phenomenon across the EU, especially at primary and secondary education levels. In the case of higher education instead, the results were more mixed (see Table 1), probably due to the nature of the data employed in the empirical analysis, which covers only public funding sources but disregards spending by households, philanthropists, international institutions, etc. In contrast to primary and secondary education, public financial support for tertiary education (which is generally not mandatory) covers only a part of total education costs (with the remaining being filled from private sources). In this context, such mixed results for tertiary education are not quite unexpected. In fact, some recent policy initiatives envisaging a shift in the cost burden from governments to parents and/or students have been taken mainly with respect to tertiary education funding support (e.g., via higher tuition fees, fiscal incentives for student loans, etc.). If this trend in policy changes will continue in the future, it would definitely help to reduce pressure on public budgets. Some forms of cost-sharing might also arise at lower education levels like, for example, private tutoring to compensate for poor/insufficient teaching that usually arises as a consequence of lower public financial support. However, there are good reasons to expect harder public scrutiny in case these practices become the norm rather than the exception (the last paragraph in section 2 lists some reference studies discussing the interaction between education and redistribution policies, and the preferences of the median-voter).

As already suggested in section 4.1 above, growing labour productivity (at least at a faster pace than wages so that unit labour costs are kept in check) might be a way to tackle the ‘cost disease’ problem over the long-term. Indeed, the ‘progressive’ sector can more efficiently leverage physical capital and technology to deliver overall productivity gains (despite stagnation in other sectors). However, this productivity-enhancing mechanism can be strengthened when human capital (instead of simply labour) enters the production function of the ‘progressive’ sector. In fact, some recent extensions of the Baumol model include more positive interactions between the ‘progressive’ and the ‘stagnant’ sectors as a way to achieve better economic outcomes (see Pugno, 2006). The dual causality link between education and economic development exposes, nevertheless, a range of effective policy options in this context. More importantly, it highlights a mechanism along which better designed policies can incentivize more (or more efficient) human capital accumulation, not only through the consumption of education services, but also through other forms, such as learning-by-doing, up-skilling, lifelong learning, etc.

It is important to note that some forms of human capital investment do not necessarily require public financial support (e.g., learning-by-doing), but others do so, and sometimes to a large extent (besides education, other examples include re-training and some active labour market policies). From a political economy perspective, and apart from business cycle influences, it is clear that policy-makers can shift their preferences between (short-term) redistributive policies (e.g., transfers or subsidies) and policies incentivizing (long-term) human capital accumulation. There are probably many difficult trade-offs here that arise due to seemingly conflicting objectives. Yet, it is not necessarily the size of public spending allocated to a given policy area that this paper is concerned with, but rather the policy-decision process of adjusting/amending spending in an effort to deliver results on a clear policy mandate. In this context, the weak overall empirical evidence found for policy commitment on education could highlight risks associated with EU economic development prospects. Even if the lack of clear evidence for commitment is mostly a reflection of large heterogeneity issues in the data, it could nevertheless raise concerns with respect to real (economic and political) convergence prospects in Europe.

5 Conclusions

This paper makes two important contributions. Firstly, it uncovers some of the main economic determinants driving the dynamics of public education spending in a panel dataset spanning across EU members over the 2000–2012 period. The empirical model builds mainly on theoretical insights borrowed from Baumol (1967), Baumol and Bowen (1966), and Bowen (1980). A four-equation system is proposed to resolve the spending allocation problem inherent in a public budgeting process, with three equations describing the dynamics of education spending per student (at primary, secondary and tertiary levels) and a fourth one describing the dynamics of total public spending in per capita terms. The empirical results provide strong evidence that the costs of public education have been rising faster than general prices (proxied here by the aggregate unit labour costs), despite accounting for growing real income/demand effects (proxied by GDP per capita). Besides confirming the theories on which the specification of the model was built, such a finding also exposes, unfortunately, the long-term affordability challenge of public education investment.

Secondly, the empirical setting above is used to investigate whether policy commitment has been a major determinant driving the dynamics of public education spending in Europe. I draw on two main policy agendas and select the share of early school leavers as a relevant policy objective for the EU member states over the whole 2000–2012 period. Then, expanding on the previous model specification, I formulate an empirical equivalent of a policy rule that would determine how education spending decisions are related to past progresses in the policy objective. Nonetheless, I find only weak overall statistical evidence of policy commitment to education across Europe, most likely due to large heterogeneity issues in the dataset. Moreover, the empirical results seem to be sensitive to some basic robustness checks.

Finally, it might be worth pointing out some further research directions. A possible follow-up could attempt to include determinants that draw more heavily on political economy considerations to reflect changes in political and/or institutional aspects, different financing mechanisms, or analyse longer time periods (see Busemeyer, 2007). Moreover, direct extensions of the present analysis of commitment to other policy domains remain possible, especially in the area of employment and social security, although a different theoretical background would be required in this case.

Notes

  1. See the official communication of the European Council from March 2000 at http://www.consilium.europa.eu/en/uedocs/cms_data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/00100-r1.en0.htm and the conclusions of the European Council from June 2010 at http://www.consilium.europa.eu/ueDocs/cms_Data/docs/pressData/en/ec/115346.pdf.

  2. As an additional proof of its policy relevance, an ambitious EU-wide target of no more than 10 % was initially specified, and later reiterated within the Europe 2020 version together with country-specific targets, in an attempt to enforce more efficient implementation and accountability.

  3. How much a government spends on education can be seen as a measure of its commitment to education according to Gylfason (2001). Some existing theoretical studies address the issue of policy commitment and time-consistent fiscal policy in general, but with careful considerations with respect to education investment in particular, e.g., Boadway et al. (1996), Gradstein (2000), Andersson and Konrad (2003).

  4. An interesting analysis in the EU context is provided in Dragomirescu-Gaina et al. (2015), who discuss the positive interactions between labour productivity and education choices with a long-term perspective.

  5. Same arguments can be made if one groups public spending on education and health-care together (as long-term investments in human capital) and contrasts them with spending on other public policy areas like employment and social security (which can also be seen as investments in human capital, but from a rather short-term perspective).

  6. This can be seen mostly in the significant drop in the relative prices of information-communication & technology (ICT) equipment (compared to general prices) over the last decades.

  7. Besides labour mobility, several other factors might also contribute: nominal rigidities in setting wages, high unionization levels etc.

  8. At this point, an interested reader might notice the striking similarities between the work of Baumol and the parallel research in international economics done by Balassa (1964) and Samuelson (1964). In a similar modelling setting, two sectors (i.e., the tradable and the non-tradable sector) are characterized by different productivity dynamics, but the convergence of nominal wages later drives domestic inflation higher and generates real appreciation of the domestic currency.

  9. This paper uses first-differences of the data, but a very similar approach is employed in Busemeyer (2007), who uses the residuals from an estimated autoregressive AR(1) model in levels.

  10. See Jefferson (2005) for a survey on empirical evidence related to the causality link between education financing and students’ performances. Two more recent but extensive reviews of the previous literature that are on school and teacher’s characteristics are Hanushek and Woessmann (2010) and Glewwe et al. (2011).

  11. For example Gundlach et al. (2001) compute sector-specific productivity in the education sector based on the results of standardized achievement tests for U.S.

  12. Heterogeneity might still remain an unsolved issue, despite estimating a model specification in first-differences that control for time invariant characteristics.

  13. The inclusion in the regression of the capital expenditures’ share instead of non-personnel costs’ share (which is the second biggest contributor to total public education spending) is just a matter of choice. Obviously, one cannot include all three components of public education spending due to collinearity concerns. In this case, capital spending might even provide a clearer interpretation of the results because of its explicit content.

  14. One can argue (and this would be in line with some existing empirical studies) that teachers’ age and gender composition are also important determinants of overall education spending; yet, data availability was the main drawback for not using more detailed indicators as controls. Also, one should be careful not to overstate the importance of some qualitative indicators in a time-series analysis; most of these indicators, e.g., describing schools’ organizational methods or other institutional dimensions, might have only a one-time effect (see discussion in Wolff et al., 2014) and would therefore not appear as significant in a time-series regression analysis.

  15. Please note that this would not represent an empirical formulation of a transmission mechanism—from spending public resources to reaching specific outcomes—mainly because the causality in the text above runs backwards.

  16. The number of FTE pupil/students used to compute the COFOG-based spending per student at the ISCED 0–1 level correspond only to ISCED 1 pupils, thus excluding ISCED 0 pupils.

  17. This is a common finding in empirical studies when the two regressors involved are correlated. However, in my case, the correlation is not high enough to render any of the coefficients statistically insignificant. Therefore, I take this as evidence of their different content and significance in explaining the dynamics of education spending.

  18. In principle, the share of teachers’ wages in education spending would reflect the sensitive balance that governments need to strike between human (e.g., teachers) and physical capital (e.g., schools) when it comes to allocating public funds.

  19. Although not explicitly treated here, education quality might be an important element in the policy discussion. Still, it remains an open question whether consistent (as opposed to one-time) improvements in education quality are possible at all (see Wolff et al., 2014). Meanwhile, there is plenty of space to improve the existing quantitative measures of education attainment, such as ESL.

  20. A never-ending quest for lower ESL values would be inefficient and waste important financial resources when policy-makers face an allocation problem and different policy objectives. Moreover, given the increased efforts to foster mobility across EU countries (e.g., ERASMUS+), most differences between countries should be mitigated through migration or internationalization of education over the long-run. In light of these arguments, ‘policy commitment’ appears also in the reverse situation when spending is reduced if the progress is satisfactory, thus facilitating a linear interpretation of the model.

  21. Historically, some EU countries have consistently registered very low ESL values over the 2000–2012 period, among them: AT, CZ, DK, FI, HR, LT, PL, SE, SI and SK. Other members such as CY, DE, FR, IE, LU and NL have managed to reach single-digit ESL levels only over the most recent years (i.e., 2010–2012). The rest of the EU members (representing about half of the total EU28) were still above the 10 % EU-wide target as of 2012.

  22. Europe 2020 agenda has introduced country-specific targets for ESL. However, these targets were adopted after the year 2010 (though at different moments) and were therefore not available for most of the period under consideration here. Only as an exercise, I have used the deviations from these politically ‘announced’ country-specific targets, but the results were not significant (result are available from the author). If anything, this highlights the lack of relevance (both political and empirical) of the announced targets, thus supporting the use of a series of reference values in the present evaluation of policy commitment.

  23. I use EU27 averages since data availability for EU28 is severely limited.

References

  • Ahmad N, Lequiller F, Marianna P, Pilat D, Schreyer P, Wolfl A (2003) Comparing labour productivity growth in the OECD area: the role of measurement, OECD-STI Working Paper No. 14/03

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersson F, Konrad KA (2003) Human capital investment and globalization in extortionary states. J Public Econ 87(7):1539–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Archibald RB, Feldman DH (2008) Explaining increases in higher education costs. J Higher Educ 79(3):268–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balassa B (1964) The purchasing-power parity doctrine: A reappraisal. J Polit Econ 72:584–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol WJ (1967) Macroeconomics of unbalanced growth: the anatomy of urban crisis. Am Econ Rev 57(3):415–26

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, WJ (2012). The cost disease: Why computers get cheaper and health care doesn’t. Yale university press. http://qrixqln.yalebooks.com/yupbooks/excerpts/Baumol_excerpt.pdf.

  • Baumol WJ, Bowen WG (1966) Performing arts: The economic dilemma. Twentieth Century Fund, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Benabou R (1996) Inequality and growth. NBER Macroecon Annu 11:11–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benabou R (2002) Tax and Education Policy in a Heterogeneous‐Agent Economy: What Levels of Redistribution Maximize Growth and Efficiency? Econometrica 70(2):481–517

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boadway R, Marceau N, Marchand M (1996) Investment in education and the time inconsistency of redistributive tax policy. Economica 63:171–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowen HR (1980) The costs of higher education: How much do colleges and universities spend per student and how much should they spend? Jossey-Bass, San Francisco

    Google Scholar 

  • Busemeyer MR (2007) Determinants of public education spending in 21 OECD democracies, 1980–2001. J Eur Public Policy 14(4):582–610

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen X, Moul CC (2014) Disease or utopia? Testing Baumol in education. Econ Lett 122(2):220–3

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delaney JA, Doyle WR (2011) State spending on higher education: Testing the balance wheel over time. J Educ Finance 36(4):343–68

    Google Scholar 

  • Dragomirescu-Gaina C, Elia L, Weber A (2015) A fast-forward look at tertiary education attainment in Europe 2020. J Policy Model 37(5):804–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly W (2001) The middle class consensus and economic development. J Econ Growth 6(4):317–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez R, Rogerson R (1995) On the political economy of education subsidies. Rev Econ Stud 62(2):249–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez R, Rogerson R (1996). Income distribution, communities, and the quality of public education. Quarterly J Econ. 111(1):135–64.

  • Fernandez R, Rogerson R (1998). Public education and income distribution: A dynamic quantitative evaluation of education-finance reform. Am Econ Review. 88(4):813–33.

  • Fernandez R, Rogerson R (2001). The determinants of public education expenditures: Longer-run evidence from the states. J Educ Finance. 27(1):567–83.

  • Glewwe PW, Hanushek EA, Humpage SD, Ravina R (2011). School resources and educational outcomes in developing countries: A review of the literature from 1990 to 2010. National Bureau of Economic Research, No. 17554. http://www.nber.org/papers/w17554.

  • Gradstein M (2000) An economic rationale for public education: the value of commitment. J Monet Econ 45(2):463–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gradstein M, Justman M (1997) Democratic choice of an education system: implications for growth and income distribution. J Econ Growth 2(2):169–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gundlach E, Wossmann L, Gmelin J (2001) The decline of schooling productivity in OECD countries. Econ J 111(471):135–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gylfason T (2001) Natural resources, education, and economic development. Eur Econ Rev 45(4):847–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek EA (2003) The Failure of Input‐based Schooling Policies. Econ J 113(485):F64–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek EA, Woessmann L (2010). The economics of international differences in educational achievement. National Bureau of Economic Research, No. 15949. http://www.nber.org/papers/w15949.

  • Hartwig J (2008) What drives health care expenditure? Baumol’s model of’unbalanced growth’ revisited. J Health Econ 27(3):603–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hartwig J (2011) Can Baumol’s model of unbalanced growth contribute to explaining the secular rise in health care expenditure? An alternative test. Appl Econ 43(2):173–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Humphreys BR (2000). Do business cycles affect state appropriations to higher education? Southern Econ. J. 67(2):398–413.

  • Jefferson AL (2005) Student Performance: Is More Money the Answer? J Educ Finance 31(2):111–24

    Google Scholar 

  • Kane TJ (1999) The price of admission: Rethinking how Americans pay for college. The Brookings Institution Press, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus WD (2008) Baumol’s diseases: a macroeconomic perspective. BE J Macroecon 8:1

    Google Scholar 

  • Pugno M (2006) The service paradox and endogenous economic growth. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 17(1):99–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P (1964) Theoretical notes on trade problems. Rev Econ Stat 23:145–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sasaki H (2007) The rise of service employment and its impact on aggregate productivity growth. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 18(4):438–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shelton CA (2007) The size and composition of government expenditure. J Public Econ 91:2230–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wolff EN, Baumol WJ, Saini AN (2014) A comparative analysis of education costs and outcomes: The United States vs. other OECD countries. Econ Educ Rev 39:1–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Leandro Elia, the editor (Sara de la Rica) and an anonymous reviewer of this journal for comments and suggestions that helped me streamline the analysis presented here. Comments from Stan van Alphen and Lene Mejer on a preliminary version of this paper are also acknowledged. Obviously, the usual disclaimer applies and all the remaining errors are mine. The paper builds and expands on a work project that started during my stay at the Econometrics and Applied Statistics Unit, DG Joint Research Centre, European Commission.

Responsible editor: Sara de la Rica​

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Catalin Dragomirescu-Gaina.

Additional information

Competing interests

The IZA Journal of European Labor Studies is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The author declares that he/she has observed these principles.

Appendix

Appendix

This appendix presents a sensitivity check of the estimated model coefficients displayed for both specifications (4) and (7) in Table 2. This sensitivity check addresses heterogeneity concerns with respect to countries included in the sample and consists in estimating the same model specification, but excluding one country at a time. The resulting ‘shadow coefficients’ are plotted in the figure below, where the x-axis lists the excluded country. The advantages of a four-equation system can be most clearly exposed using a simple standard deviation measure to reflect the departure of the ‘shadow coefficients’ from the ones reported in specifications (4) or (7). What is probably less clear in the figure, but becomes evident when displaying the raw standard deviations (henceforth sdev.) of the ‘shadow coefficients’, is that the outliers now play a less important role (though the bias in the estimated coefficients cannot be entirely eliminated). The three-equation system exhibits a sdev. of 5.94, 4.29 and 3.44% for the ‘shadow coefficients associated with ULCs in equations 1, 2, and 3, respectively, and 4.02, 5.82 and 3.75% for GDP per capita. Similarly, the four-equation system exhibits a sdev. of 5.46, 4.19 and 3.12% for ULCs in equations 1, 2, and 3, respectively, and 3.73, 5.77 and 3.59% for GDP per capita.

Moreover, the figure above suggests that the overall sample might contain some gross outliers (which seem to introduce a bias in the estimated coefficients) such as: BG, CY, CZ, GR, HU, LT, LV, MT, RO, and SI. These findings are not surprising since some of these countries have suffered harsh adjustments in their fiscal policies, including their public expenditures: RO, LT and LV implemented broad austerity programs negotiated with the international financial institutions, mostly in 2010 (the 25% cut in public wages in RO and LV, and the 15% cut in LT have mostly affected education, health-care and other related public sectors with large employment shares). Others such as GR, and to a smaller extent HU, have been among the countries that required international financial assistance in the aftermath of the recent global economic and European sovereign crisis. Countries such as ES, IE, IT, and PT have also benefited from different forms of EU financial support, but these countries do not seem to bias the estimated ‘shadow coefficients’ according to the figure above. However, most (if not all) EU members have undertaken some adjustments in their public spending policies over the recent periods, especially as a consequence of the sovereign crisis that has increased the pressure on public finances across the board.

Just as an illustration of the possible effects introduced in the model by the outliers identified above and/or the recent European sovereign crisis, I depart from specifications (4) and (7) from Table 2 and illustrate four additional specifications that include: (i) country-specific dummies, but only for the list of nominated outliers above, i.e., BG, CY, CZ, GR, HU, LT, LV, MT, RO, SI, and (ii) time dummies that cover the whole estimation period. The alternative specifications are labeled (4.i), (4.ii), (7.i) and (7.ii) and are displayed in Table 4 below. Two main findings are worth mentioning here. Firstly, as expected, correcting for outliers has generated an overall increase in the explanatory power of the empirical model (as captured by the R2), especially at the ISCED 0–1 and ISCED 2–4 levels. Secondly, the coefficients associated with ULCs and GDP per capita have remained statistically significant across all the alternative specifications, and this is a strong confirmation for the importance of the economic determinants identified in section 2.

Table 4 Alternative estimates for public education spending per (FTE) student – tackling outliers

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Dragomirescu-Gaina, C. An empirical inquiry into the determinants of public education spending in Europe. IZA J Labor Stud 4, 25 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40174-015-0049-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s40174-015-0049-7

Keywords