Open Access

Revisiting German labour market reform effects—a panel data analysis for occupational labour markets

IZA Journal of European Labor Studies20165:14

DOI: 10.1186/s40174-016-0064-3

Received: 12 December 2015

Accepted: 21 April 2016

Published: 26 July 2016

Abstract

The role of the 2000’s German labour market reforms in boosting the German economy has been widely discussed. Considering that one of the main objectives of these reforms was to improve the matching process on the labour market, I use high-frequency administrative data to present new details regarding the development of job-matching performance from 2000 to 2011. Matching productivity increased during all reform stages. Increases in matching productivity have become smaller from 2009. The analysis shows also differences and commonalities in the matching productivity changes on occupational labour markets.

Keywords

Labour market reforms Unemployment Vacancies Matching model Panel data Occupational labour markets

JEL Classification

C23 J44 J64

1 Introduction

The tenth anniversary of the German labour market reforms has been accompanied by a lively discussion regarding the contributions of these reforms to the development of the German labour market and the German economy as a whole (Burda and Hunt 2011; Dustmann et al. 2014; Fitzenberger 2009; Gartner and Fujita 2014; Hertweck and Sigrist 2012; Krebs and Scheffel 2013; Möller 2010; Rinne and Zimmermann 2012, 2013). Whether the results of various studies imply that German labour market policy in the last decade can thus be regarded as a role model for other countries seems to depend on policy makers’ expectations for these reforms. In particular, it is debatable whether the reforms were expected to boost the entire German economy and raise its competitiveness. However, it is clear that one of the main objectives of the reforms was explicit in its mandate to improve matching processes on the German labour market (Hartz et al. 2002) because Germany suffered from a high degree of structural unemployment in the early 2000s.

In this paper, I present comprehensive details regarding the development of the job-matching function and its performance before and after the reforms took effect. The German labour market reforms were implemented in four stages and spanned the period from 2003 to 2005. The laws that were implemented are referred to as Hartz I to Hartz IV and were named after the head of the expert commission that worked out the substantial propositions for the German labour market reforms (Hartz et al. 2002). In January 2003, the first two reform stages were implemented (Hartz I and II). The third stage, Hartz III, followed in January 2004 and the last stage, Hartz IV, was implemented in January 2005. Additionally and following these reform stages, in 2006, the maximum number of months of unemployment benefits was reduced. Few studies have shed light on the direction and structure of the reform’s effects on job matching productivity. Fahr and Sunde (2009) reported better matching for the aggregated German labour market after the first three reform stages (Hartz I/II and Hartz III) had been implemented. Klinger and Rothe (2012) used newer and richer data, which enabled these authors to analyse the last reform stage (Hartz IV in 2005) and to distinguish between long- and short-term unemployed. Overall, these authors also found that the reforms had positive effects on matching efficiency, particularly after Hartz I/II (2003) and III (2004) were introduced. In addition, they found stronger reform effects for the long-term unemployed. However, the last reform stage (Hartz IV)—consisting of a fundamental change in the tax-financed and means-tested unemployment benefit scheme—did not lead to further positive effects. The same authors explain this finding using statistical effects because the number of unemployed increased sharply in 2005 due to the changes under Hartz IV. Hillmann (2009), who also used newer data, found that Hartz IV had positive effects; her analysis constructed the reform dummy differently for Hartz IV.1 Finally, Klinger and Weber (2014) used data from 1979 to 2009 to analyse the inward shift of the Beveridge curve after the reform years and were able to generally confirm the positive effects of the reforms on matching efficiency, although these authors also found that the positive trend of matching efficiency came to an end in 2009. Clearly, these studies have shed light on the temporal and structural properties of the effects of these reforms.

However, until now, it has not been known whether the positive changes in matching efficiency can be observed for all jobs or how the matching efficiencies changed in the relevant partial labour markets and particularly in occupational labour markets. Another relevant question is whether the effects changed temporarily or permanently during (extreme) economic situations, such as the 2008/2009 financial crisis.

This paper complements previous research by estimating the parameters of a macroeconomic matching function on the basis of detailed, high-frequency and more recent administrative data for the 2000–2011 period; thus, it includes the span of the 2008/2009 financial crisis. As this study’s first step, I deliver an exact and detailed analysis of the evolution of the matching productivity. Therefore, this study also contributes to the strand of theoretic literature (compare, e.g. with previous studies by Krause and Uhlig, 2012; Krebs and Scheffel, 2013, 2014; Launov and Wälde, 2015) that evaluates further effects of labour market reforms, e.g. on unemployment and others, and refers to the estimated changes in the matching efficiencies (like in Fahr and Sunde 2009; Klinger and Rothe 2012). In the second step, I present an analyses of occupational labour markets because it is known that matching efficiency varies in different occupational labour markets, as shown in Fahr and Sunde (2006); Stops and Mazzoni (2010). To distinguish occupational labour markets, I use the German occupational classification scheme according to Blossfeld (1983). It is possible to identify the temporal evolution of matching productivity by estimating yearly time fixed effects that can be interpreted as year-specific deviations from average matching productivity during the observation period. To identify the temporal evolution of matching productivity in occupational labour markets, I complement the model with interaction dummy variables that combine yearly and occupational labour market effects.

My analysis corroborates the previous findings of positive changes in the matching productivity during and after all the reform stages and clarifies that there are also positive changes after Hartz IV. Matching productivity hardly increased during the recession in 2009; in specifications without a control for the business cycle, a significant ‘crisis’ dip is observable. Furthermore, the results reveal positive changes in the matching productivity during and after the reform years in all occupational labour markets. However, the results for the point estimates suggest some differences in more recent changes of matching productivity, but the changes from year to year are not significant.

The remainder of this paper is organised as follows. In Section 2, I describe some relevant facts regarding the German labour market reforms and their (theoretical) implications for matching productivity. Then, I present the theoretical foundations of the macroeconomic matching function, the interpretation of its parameters, and, finally, information about the occupational labour market structure the analysis will be related to. Section 3 presents details about the data used for the analysis and certain descriptive key statistics. Section 4 explains the empirical strategy and reports and discusses estimation results. Robustness checks that generally confirm these results and that are based on both another theoretical perspective of job matching and higher aggregated data are reported in Section 5. Section 6 contains the main conclusions.

2 Labour market reforms and job matching

Empirical findings for the early 2000s in Germany reveal high and persistent unemployment that was independent of the business cycle (Klinger and Rothe 2012). Furthermore, there were discussions regarding opportunities to measure the efforts of public job placement services and to make the job placement organisation more efficient. Therefore, the government stipulated four laws that were implemented in three waves in 2003, 2004 and 2005. In doing so, the government considered the working results of an expert commission, the so-called Hartz commission. Each of the Hartz I to IV reform laws consisted of various components that refer to the organisation and rules of the labour market. Essentially, three elements of these reforms aimed at an increase of the job-finding rate of unemployed workers: raising the effectiveness and efficiency of the Federal Employment Agency; more activation and higher self-responsibility of the unemployed (principle of ‘Promoting and demanding’);2 easing of labour market policy (see for further details, e.g. Bieber et al. 2005; Jacobi and Kluve 2007; Klinger and Rothe 2012; Ochel 2005).

It generally remains an empirical question whether and to what extent all the reform efforts affect labour market outcomes, such as the efficiency of matching. It is not possible to identify the total extent and variation in the described efforts within the different reform stages. Nevertheless, it is possible to evaluate changes in matching productivity before, during and after the reform years with a macroeconomic matching function framework.

The macroeconomic matching function and the matching process behind it were conceived by Diamond (1982a, b); Mortensen (1982); Pissarides (1979, 1985). The matching process begins with the decisions of firms to create a new job or to fill a vacancy (job creation decisions) and decisions of (unemployed) persons regarding how intensely to search for a new job (job search decisions) (Pissarides 2000, p. xi). Firms spend time, financial and personnel resources for job advertisements, screening, training and vocational adjustments. Job seekers spend resources for job search and application procedures. Unemployed persons and firms are randomly matched and begin to bargain regarding wages.

The basic model assumes homogeneous unemployed persons and homogeneous jobs. The activities of both market sides are matching technologies. The processes behind these activities are not explicitly modelled, so the matching process can be compared with a black box (Petrongolo and Pissarides 2001). The variables U, V and M represent the stock of unemployed, the stock of vacancies and the flows of new hires, respectively. The resulting matching function f(U,V) is specified in a Cobb-Douglas form:
$$ M_{t}=A_{t}U_{t}^{\beta_{Us}}V_{t}^{\beta_{Vs}}, $$
(1)

where A describes the ‘augmented’ matching productivity. Another important assumption lies behind the approach—workers and firms are randomly matched and originate from the pool of existing unemployed workers and job vacancies.

My analysis refers to changes in the parameter A of the matching function that result of changes in the institutional framework of the labour market resulting from the reforms. The central question is whether this parameter changed after implementing the reforms. Therefore, I assume that this parameter varies over time; thus, A t is different for different observation periods, whereas the elasticities remain constant during the entire observation period.

This model differs from Klinger and Rothe (2012) and Fahr and Sunde (2009), who both assumed that there is a constant augmented productivity for the observation period before the reforms were implemented and a (possibly) different augmented productivity after the reform was introduced.3 In the model described above, this term differs from observation period to observation period. Therefore, it is possible to compare the temporal evolution of augmented productivity, which is similar to Klinger and Weber (2014), who estimate an ‘extended matching function’ that contains a time-varying matching efficiency parameter that is decomposed in a cyclical and a trend component. However, their identification strategy differs from the strategy utilised herein because it is based on a multivariate time series and correlated unobserved components model, whereas the identification made in this paper is based on variations in repeated observations in regional and occupational labour markets.

To analyse the reforms’ effects on occupational labour markets, I use the occupational classification scheme derived by Blossfeld (1983), who divides the labour market into 12 broader occupational categories and a category ‘[0] Not assignable’ (Table 1). These categories can be roughly assigned to qualification levels and sectors. Thus, this classification can be understood as an approximation of occupational labour markets that are assumed to be separate from one another and as a good (exogenous) base for the analysis of changes in the matching efficiency of occupational labour markets.
Table 1

Occupational categories

[1]

AGR agrarian occupations

[2]

EMB simple manual occupations

[3]

QMB qualified manual occupations

[4]

TEC technicians

[5]

ING engineers

[6]

EDI simple service occupations

[7]

QDI qualified service occupations

[8]

SEMI semi-professions

[9]

PROF professions

[10]

EVB simple business and administrative occupations

[11]

QVB qualified business and administrative occupations

[12]

MAN manager

[0]

Not assignable

Source: Occupational categories are taken from Blossfeld (1983)

Again, I assume constant matching elasticities of unemployed and vacancies (stocks and flows) in the economy, but the augmented productivity term A tb now varies with the occupational categories b and observation periods t:
$$ M_{tb}=A_{tb}U_{tb}^{\beta_{Us}}V_{tb}^{\beta_{Vs}} $$
(2)

3 Data

I use a unique administrative panel data set of 329 occupational orders in 402 NUTS3 regions with 138 observation periods from January 2000 to June 2011. The occupational orders are coded according to the German occupational classification scheme (three digits, Kldb88).4 All the data stem from the Federal Employment Agency. The groups are assigned to the 13 occupational labour markets described in the previous section.5

I use monthly data regarding flows from unemployment to employment and stocks of unemployed and registered vacancies. Table 2 shows some descriptive statistics.
Table 2

Descriptive statistics

Measure

Monthly averages 2000–2011 (in 1000)

 

Mean

Minimum

Maximum

Standard deviation

Employment inflows M

259

144

412

51

Unemployment stock U

3750

2761

4950

570

Registered vacancies stock V

332

173

460

79

Source: Own calculation based on the administrative data from the statistics department of the Federal Employment Agency 2000–2011

To get unbiased matching parameter estimations, I adjust the data set by observations for occupations and NUTS3 regions, respectively, in which vacancies, unemployed or flows into employment are reported as zero, which leads to an unbalanced panel data structure with about 2.394 million observations.

Previous literature reported several concerns regarding the vacancy and the unemployment series that should be borne in mind. The first concern is about the time series of vacancies. According to Fahr and Sunde (2009), the time series before 2001 reveal a certain lack of information about the region where the vacancy is situated. However, this is true for ‘only a few’ NUTS3 regions (Bundesagentur für Arbeit 2016) and the cleansing procedure, described above, also accounts for that. In addition, the time series of the vacancy statistics were further improved in July 2010 and recomputed again until January 2000 (Hartmann and Reimer 2010). Therefore, the values from different months within the chosen observation period from January 2000 to June 2011 should be better comparable than before this revision in 2010.

The time series for the unemployed are also improved since the mentioned studies were published. However, regarding the statistics of recipients of the means tested unemployment benefits II (UB II, ‘Arbeitslosengeld II’) in the years 2005 and 2006, it cannot be ruled out that some of the recipients are recorded two times in case unemployed persons changed the provider of the UB II. Only a small part of the recipients of means tested unemployment benefits were affected by this, e.g. an analysis of the effect of the revision showed that the stocks of unemployed changed less than one permille compared to the previous statistics and there are only a few NUTS3 regions where the changes are more important regarding (only) the inflows in employment (Bundesagentur für Arbeit 2015; Engelhardt et al. 2014). An other concern raised by Fahr and Sunde (2009) was that the definition of unemployment changed in January 2005 with the result that the number of unemployed increased due to statistical reasons.6 Klinger and Rothe (2012) suggests to control for the observation periods when the change happened by including a dummy for the first quarter in 2015 in their empirical model. The analysis here is based on monthly or yearly time effects. According to the results in Klinger and Rothe (2012), this would imply that the ‘break’ in January 2005 could affect the monthly effects of the first quarter and the year effect of 2005.

Figure 1 shows the time series of unemployment stocks, unemployment inflows, vacancy stocks, vacancy inflows and flows from unemployment into employment and their trends. The trends are computed using the Hodrick Prescott filter (Hodrick and Prescott 1997). It is clear that there is a change in the trends from 2003 to 2005, i.e., the reform years. Whereas the trends of the unemployment outflows and inflows and the stocks of registered vacancies decreased before and increased after the reform years, the stock and inflows of the unemployed increased before and decreased after the reform years. However, the strongest changes are shown in the unemployment and the vacancy stocks, whereas the outflows reveal only slight changes in the trend.
Fig. 1

Time series of the key figures for the 2000–2011 analysis. Source: Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency, own computations. Trends are computed with the Hodrick Prescott filter (Hodrick and Prescott 1997) with smoothing parameter α=129,600 (according to Ravn and Uhlig 2002)

4 Empirical strategy and results

4.1 Aggregated estimations

At first, I estimate regression equations that are based on the logarithm version of Eq. (1) and complemented by further variables that are included stepwise:
$$ \log {M}_{ijt}=a+{\beta}_{Us} \log {U}_{ijt}+{\beta}_{Vs} \log {V}_{ijt}+{\mu}_{ij}+{\boldsymbol{\uptheta} \mathbf{X}}_{ijt}+\gamma {\mathrm{GDP}}_{\mathrm{cyc},FS}(i),\mathrm{year}(t)+{d}_t+{\varepsilon}_{ijt} $$
(3)

Here, the term logM ijt denotes the logarithm of the flows from unemployment to employment for region i, occupational order j and observation period t. The parameter a is a constant and thus a component of the logarithm of the average augmented matching productivity. The variables logU and logV are the logarithms of the unemployed and vacancy stocks, whereas β Us and β Vs denote the matching elasticities of the unemployed and vacancies, respectively. The column vector X contains a set of four control variables in its columns: the share of female employees on all employees subject to social security contributions and two variables with the shares of employees with ‘vocational training’ and the shares of employees with an ‘academic degree’ (with reference group ‘without occupational training’). These variables are based on data for the occupational orders and the NUTS 3 regions. The fourth variable contains the average age of the population in each NUTS 3 region. These four variables are included in all specifications to control for some developments in the (working) population that could also potentially have an impact on the development of the matching efficiency.7 The row vector θ contains the coefficients of these control variables. Furthermore, the regression equation contains a fixed effect, μ ij , for each regional occupational labour market, ij, that can be interpreted as the occupational and local area specific augmented productivity. Finally, this basic specification includes also an i.i.d. error term, ε ijt , for each observation.

In the next step, I include the cyclical component of real gross domestic product, GDPcyc,FS(i),year(t), for the federal state, FS, that region i belongs to and the year that the observation period, t, belongs to. The coefficient for this variable is γ. Then, I include monthly time fixed effects, d t , that are—for the moment—the coefficients of interest. These variables are effect coded, and their coefficients can thus be directly interpreted as the monthly deviations from the average augmented matching productivity for the 2000 to 2011 observation period.8 The reference period is January 2000.

Finally, I modify the regression above by including dummy variables d q (t) for the first, second, or third quarter of the year. Furthermore, I substitute the monthly observation period time fixed effects with year fixed effects d year(t). This variable is also effect coded,9 and the reference year is 2000. Thus, the latter variable can be interpreted as the yearly seasonal adjusted deviation from the average of augmented matching productivity during the 2001 to 2011 observation period. The regression equation is then as follows:
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \log M_{ijt}=a+\beta_{Us} \log U_{ijt} + \beta_{Vs} \log V_{ijt} + \mathbf{\theta X}_{ijt} + \gamma \text{GDP}_{\mathrm{cyc,FS}(i),\text{year}(t)} + &\cdots&\\ \cdots + d_{q(t)} + d_{\text{year}(t)}+ \mu_{ij}+&\epsilon_{ijt}& \end{array} $$
(4)

In panel data sets like the one I utilised here, cross-sectional dependence cannot generally be ruled out. To get further indications whether cross-sectional dependence has to be considered, I calculated Pesaran’s CD statistic. This statistic is the basis for a test for cross-sectional dependence in the residuals (Pesaran (2004)). The results reveal that the Null of strong cross-sectional dependence in the residuals cannot be rejected.10 Furthermore, another issue of panel data sets could be temporal autocorrelation of the residuals and heteroscedastic error terms. Therefore, I calculated Driscoll-Kraay standard errors that account for general forms of spatial and temporal dependence and heteroscedaticity in case of a relative large time dimension and a quite larger number of cross-sectional units (Driscoll and Kraay 1998).11

The results of the estimations can be found in Table 3. Column FE 1 of Table 3 refers to the basic specification. As expected from the theoretical model, the matching elasticities of the unemployed and vacancy stocks are both significantly positive. Furthermore, the matching elasticity of the unemployed is higher than the matching elasticity of the vacancies; this result corroborates previous studies for Germany (Burda and Wyplosz, 1994; Entorf, 1998; Fahr and Sunde, 2004; Klinger and Rothe, 2012; Stops and Mazzoni, 2010).
Table 3

Fixed effects estimation results based on the data set disaggregated by occupations and NUTS3 regions

 

Dependent variable: logM

 

FE 1

FE 2

FE 3

FE 4

β Us

0.580***

0.592***

0.624***

0.626***

 

(0.013)

(0.012)

(0.009)

(0.010)

β Vs

0.065***

0.058***

0.039***

0.044***

 

(0.006)

(0.005)

(0.004)

(0.004)

Year dummies, effect coded (reference year: 2000):

d 2001

   

−0.116***

    

(0.031)

d 2002

   

−0.149***

    

(0.026)

d 2003

   

−0.122***

    

(0.017)

d 2004

   

−0.111***

    

(0.019)

d 2005

   

−0.082***

    

(0.022)

d 2006

   

−0.030**

    

(0.014)

d 2007

   

0.066***

    

(0.020)

d 2008

   

0.143***

    

(0.015)

d 2009

   

0.146***

    

(0.017)

d 2010

   

0.178***

    

(0.021)

d 2011

   

0.152***

    

(0.020)

γ

 

1.681***

1.363***

1.377***

  

(0.557)

(0.272)

(0.271)

a

−4.533***

−4.785***

−0.896**

−0.826**

 

(0.633)

(0.614)

(0.397)

(0.410)

Control variables

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Monthly time dummies

No

No

Yes

No

Quarter dummies

No

No

No

Yes

Observations

2,393,683

2,393,683

2,393,683

2,393,683

Number of groups

55,316

55,316

55,316

55,316

Within R-squared

0.236

0.240

0.304

0.275

Driscoll-Kraay standard errors in parentheses. Column FE 3 includes monthly time fixed effects with effect coding (reference period is January 2000); compare with Fig. 2, left panel. Control variables are the share of female workers, the shares of workers at different skill levels (‘vocational training’ and ‘academic degree,’ reference group is ‘without vocational training’) in each NUTS3 region and occupation, and the average age by the population by NUTS3 regions. The estimated coefficients are provided on request. The estimated coefficients are provided on request

*** p <0.01, ** p <0.05, * p <0.1

The results in the second column, FE 2, belong to the same specification augmented with the cyclical component of the yearly gross domestic product for the 16 federal states (GDPcyc,FS(i),year(t)). These results do not differ much from the results in the first column, FE 1.

The third column, FE 3, contains the results for the regression Eq. (3), including monthly time fixed effects. Compared with previous specifications, the matching elasticities of the unemployed are somewhat higher and the matching elasticities of the vacancies are lower. The monthly fixed effects are not presented in Table 3; however, their graphical representation can be found in the left panel of Fig. 2. The right panel of this figure shows the evolution of the year fixed effects of column 4 in Table 3.
Fig. 2

Month and year time fixed effects and 95 % confidence band. Notes: Specifications from Table 3, left side, are FE 3; those from the right side are FE 4—based on a data set disaggregated by occupations and NUTS3 regions. The blue dots and the vertical red lines mark the point and 95 % interval estimates, and the interval is very small in some cases. In the left panel, the dots are linked with a line to illustrate temporal development. Time fixed effects with effect coding (the reference period is January 2000 for month fixed effects or 2000 for year fixed effects, respectively)

As explained above, these variables can be interpreted as time-specific deviations from the average augmented matching productivity, where the average is normalised to zero. Accordingly, from the beginning of the observation period until 2006, the monthly deviations might be negative or positive with a seasonal pattern. In addition, beginning with the reform years, 2003–2005, and continuing forward, the monthly deviations began to increase from year to year; from 2007 onwards, the deviations are all significantly positive. These results provide the first impression of how augmented matching productivity developed after the labour market reforms were implemented in 2003 to 2005. All in all, the volatile seasonal pattern gives only a rough first impression regarding the evolution of matching productivity.

In Eq. (4), the year dummies can be interpreted as yearly deviations from the averaged augmented matching productivity and should thus give a clearer picture. Furthermore, seasonality patterns are adjusted by quarter dummies. The results of the estimations, including the yearly deviations, are reported in column 4 of Table 3. The graphical representation of the year effects for the random matching model can be found in the right panel of Fig. 2.

The yearly deviations are negative at the beginning of the observation period and begin to increase from 2002; they become significantly positive from 2007 onwards. There is hardly an increase in 2009, the year of the financial crisis, and after a further small increase in 2010, the deviation slightly decreases in 2011. The changes are small, but one can observe a significant ‘crisis dip’ in 2009 and larger elasticity and productivity coefficients based on regression equations without the business cycle variable, GDPcyc,FS(i),year(t), as a control variable; compare with columns 1 to 3 of Table 9 and the left panels of Figs. 9 and 10 in ‘Further results’ in the Appendix.

In general, it can be concluded from the results that there are positive changes in matching productivity during and after implementation of the reform; in recent years, there are only small changes. Therefore, the results are in line with the previous studies regarding the development of the matching efficiency after 2003 and 2004 (part. Fahr and Sunde 2009; Klinger and Rothe 2012; Klinger and Weber 2014). The results are different to Klinger and Rothe (2012) who did not find further increases after 2005. However, Klinger and Weber (2014) and this study found that the matching efficiency further increased in the following years.

For interpretation of the results, one should consider that the estimated time fixed effects are only the part of the augmented matching productivity parameter logA that is not explained by the business cycle, the information in the controls and the regional fixed effects. To get a more comprehensive view of the development of the matching efficiency, I calculated predictions of logA (and A), based on specifications including the business cycle variable and without. The computations of both specification are very similar and they show again clearly the ‘crisis’ dip, higher increases in the matching efficiency after the reform years than before, the same lower increases in recent year, including 2011. More details can be found in ‘Predicted matching efficiencies’ in the Appendix.

4.2 Occupational labour markets

Figure 3 describes the development of the trends of our key figures—flows from unemployment to employment, unemployment stocks, and the registered vacancy stocks—as normalised measures with index 1 first in January 2000 (left panels) and second for January 2005 (right panels).
Fig. 3

Key figures by occupational groups, normalised trends, 2000–2004 (January 2000 = 1, left panel) and 2005–2011 (January 2005=1, right panel). Source: Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency. Trends are computed with the Hodrick Prescott filter (Hodrick and Prescott 1997) with smoothing parameter α = 129,600 (according to Ravn and Uhlig 2002). [01] AGR agrarian occupations, [02] EMB simple manual occupations, [03] QMB qualified manual occupations, [04] TEC technicians, [05] ING engineers, [06] EDI simple service occupations, [07] QDI qualified service occupations, [08] SEMI semi professions, [09] PROF professions, [10] EVB simple business and administrative occupations, [11] QVB qualified business and administrative occupations, [12] MAN manager

Generally, these figures show that there is a certain heterogeneity in the development of the key figures in different occupational labour markets, which leads me to the conclusion that I can expect different results regarding the analysis of the changes of the matching elasticity in these markets. Thus, I separately estimate the deviations of the averaged augmented productivity for the occupational labour markets, b(j), that the occupational order j is assigned to. The regression is equivalent to the logarithm version of Eq. (2). Again, this specification is stepwise complemented by additional variables:
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \log M_{ijt}=a+\beta_{Us} \log U_{ijt} + \beta_{Vs} \log V_{ijt} + \mathbf{\theta X}_{ijt} + \text{GDP}_{\mathrm{cyc,FS}(i),\text{year}(t)} + &\cdots&\\ \cdots + d_{i} + d_{q(t)} + d_{\text{year}(t)} + d_{b(j)} + d_{b(j),\text{year}(t)} +&\epsilon_{ijt}& \end{array} $$
(5)

Here, it is not possible to separate the occupational and regional fixed effects and the occupational labour market effects, b(j), related to occupation j. Therefore, I exclude the fixed effects μ ij and I estimate an ordinary least squares (OLS) model. The model is augmented by local area effects d i , quarter dummy variables (d q(t)) and year dummies (yearly observation period fixed effects, d year(t)) with reference to year 2000 and thus the yearly specific deviations from the average augmented productivity. Furthermore, it contains dummy variables for 11 occupational categories with reference to the ‘agrarian and not assignable occupations’ (d b(j)) categories. The coefficients of these variables are equivalent to the occupational labour market’s specific deviations from average matching productivity. Finally, the model contains interaction dummies for the yearly and occupational labour market–specific deviations d b(j),year(t). Formally, the latter variable is the interaction term of the year dummies and the occupational labour market dummy variables. Again, dummy variables are effect coded with the exception of the quarter dummy (the fourth quarter is the reference period).

The results can be found in Table 4. Column OLS 1 contains the OLS estimation of a pure matching model without the business cycle variable or further dummy variables. As expected, the coefficients for the matching elasticities are again significantly positive. After including the business cycle variable (OLS 2), the coefficients hardly change. Column OLS 3 of Table 4 shows the results for the specifications, including dummy variables for year effects, quarters and occupational labour markets. In particular, the year fixed effects coefficients have a similar pattern as the results of the fixed effects estimations. Thus, the main conclusions of the previous section are unaffected. Finally, column OLS 4 reports the results of the full specification, including year- and occupational-specific interaction effects. Due to space constraints, I do not report the latter coefficients, but I show the point and interval estimations graphically in Figs. 4 and 5.
Fig. 4

Estimated sums of the yearly dummy and the yearly interaction effects and 95 % confidence band by occupational categories (part 1/2). Source: Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency, own computations. Notes: The graphs refer to the results in column OLS 4 in Table 4, based on a data set disaggregated by occupations and NUTS3 regions. The blue dots and the vertical red lines mark the point and 95 % interval estimates

Fig. 5

Estimated sums of the yearly dummy and the yearly interaction effects and 95 % confidence band by occupational categories (part 2/2). Source: Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency, own computations. Notes: Graphs refer to results in column OLS 4 in Table 4, based on the data set disaggregated by occupations and NUTS3 regions. The blue dots and the vertical red lines mark the point and 95 % interval estimates

Table 4

OLS estimation results based on data set disaggregated by occupations and NUTS3 regions

 

Dependent variable: logM

 

OLS 1

OLS 2

OLS 3

OLS 4

β Us

0.631***

0.635***

0.662***

0.662***

 

(0.006)

(0.006)

(0.007)

(0.006)

β Vs

0.127***

0.123***

0.114***

0.115***

 

(0.004)

(0.004)

(0.004)

(0.004)

Year dummies, effect coded (reference year: 2000):

d 2001

  

−0.121***

−0.131***

   

(0.031)

(0.028)

d 2002

  

−0.151***

−0.157***

   

(0.026)

(0.025)

d 2003

  

−0.112***

−0.124***

   

(0.018)

(0.020)

d 2004

  

−0.085***

−0.087***

   

(0.018)

(0.020)

d 2005

  

−0.065***

−0.059***

   

(0.021)

(0.022)

d 2006

  

−0.030**

−0.035*

   

(0.013)

(0.018)

d 2007

  

0.053**

0.066***

   

(0.021)

(0.024)

d 2008

  

0.133***

0.148***

   

(0.015)

(0.018)

d 2009

  

0.156***

0.174***

   

(0.017)

(0.017)

d 2010

  

0.169***

0.170***

   

(0.020)

(0.017)

d 2011

  

0.130***

0.137***

   

(0.022)

(0.028)

Dummies for occupational categories, effect coded (reference: [0]/[1] AGR)

[02] EMB

  

-0.016

-0.020**

   

(0.011)

(0.010)

[03] QMB

  

0.056***

0.054***

   

(0.013)

(0.008)

[04] TEC

  

−0.096***

−0.093***

   

(0.006)

(0.005)

[05] ING

  

−0.100***

−0.085***

   

(0.016)

(0.010)

[06] EDI

  

−0.102***

−0.104***

   

(0.009)

(0.007)

[07] QDI

  

0.080***

0.078***

   

(0.008)

(0.007)

[08] SEMI

  

0.095***

0.093***

   

(0.014)

(0.013)

[09] PROF

  

0.271***

0.281***

   

(0.014)

(0.011)

[10] EVB

  

−0.212***

−0.212***

   

(0.007)

(0.007)

[11] QVB

  

−0.043***

−0.043***

   

(0.007)

(0.007)

[12] MAN

  

0.005

0.003

   

(0.009)

(0.007)

γ

 

1.492**

1.559***

1.504***

  

(0.582)

(0.269)

(0.264)

a

−5.091***

−5.233***

−1.605***

−1.753***

 

(0.617)

(0.593)

(0.438)

(0.404)

Control variables

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Local area effects

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Occupational yearly interaction effects

No

No

No

Yes

Quarter dummies

No

No

Yes

Yes

Observations

2,393,683

2,393,683

2,393,683

2,393,683

R-squared

0.711

0.712

0.730

0.731

Driscoll-Kraay standard errors in parentheses. Columns OLS 4 includes yearly time and occupational category interaction effects (reference year is 2000, reference category is ‘[01] AGR Agrarian and not assignable occupations’), and all dummy variables are effect coded; compare ‘Effect coding’ in the Appendix. Control variables are the share of female workers, the shares of workers at different skill levels (‘vocational training’ and ‘academic degree,’ reference group is ‘without vocational training’) in each NUTS3 region and occupation, and the average age by the population by NUTS3 regions. The estimated coefficients are provided on request.

[01] AGR agrarian and not assignable occupations, [02] EMB simple manual occupations, [03] QMB qualified manual occupations, [04] TEC technicians, [05] ING engineers, [06] EDI simple service occupations, [07] QDI qualified service occupations, [08] SEMI semi professions, [09] PROF professions, [10] EVB simple business and administrative occupations, [11] QVB qualified business and administrative occupations, and [12] MAN manager

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Columns OLS 3 and OLS 4 reveal another finding: at the 5 % level, the occupational labour market specific deviations from the augmented productivity for the observation period are significantly negative for occupations that are assignable to a lower skill level (EMB, EDI, EVB) and for technicians (TEC) and engineers (ING). The deviations of qualified business and administrative occupations (QVB) and qualified service occupations (QDI) are insignificant, and the deviations of the remaining occupational categories are significantly positive.

In the following, I discuss the results for the year- and occupational-specific interaction effects. Figures 4 and 5 show 95 % interval estimate sums of the yearly dummy and the yearly interaction effects dummy variables in 11 panels for each occupational labour market (d year(t)+d b(j),year(t)), with the exception of the reference category ‘[AGR] agrarian and not assignable occupations’). These sums represent the yearly deviations from average occupational labour market-specific augmented productivity (d b(j)); thus, they show how the augmented productivity in a certain occupational labour market is changed based on a ‘pure’ time effect.

The common finding is that there is a positive change in the deviation from occupational labour market-specific augmented productivity after the reform years, which can be understood as an indicator that the reform had effects on the entire labour market. However, there are certain differences regarding the timing of the change and the further development of matching efficiency. In addition, differences arise during the years of the financial crisis in 2008/2009.

Regarding the structure of the time effects after the crisis, there are significantly positive effects observable from 2008 onwards, at the latest. Information regarding the timing of the effects complements previous studies that only compared matching productivity before or during the reform years and after the reform years (part., Fahr and Sunde 2009; Klinger and Rothe 2012) and also illustrates that it is hardly possible to distinguish between the effects of the different reform stages because it would imply that the consequences of each reform stage came into effect within 1 year.12 This result can hardly be corroborated based on the results in this study.13 Overall, the view on the year effects in the different occupational labour markets confirm the finding that the development of the matching efficiency is rather different in different occupational labour markets; thus, the timing of the effects is also different.

Regarding the further evolution of the time fixed effects, the results reveal that the point estimates of the effects differ between the occupational labour markets in recent years. For example, with the exception of technicians (TEC) and engineers (ING), the positive deviations decreased in at least the last years, i.e. from 2009 to 2011. However, the changes from year to year are not significant.

5 Validity and robustness checks

5.1 Another theoretical perspective: selective search

Gregg and Petrongolo (2005) state that the unstable results of papers that study the parameters of matching functions result in a certain misspecification of the matching function due to the assumption of (completely) random search. These authors propose to utilise a stock-flow matching model framework, originally derived by Coles (1994) and Coles and Smith (1998). This approach considers job searching that is not completely random. However, for this, it must state an assumption that might be understood as a further restriction of the random matching approach: the assumption is made that the agents on both sides of the market are able to sample the entire relevant part of the stocks of the other side with no friction due to the availability of quite efficient information channels. Following that, the agents who did not found adequate offers and, therefore, remain in the unemployed or vacancy stocks, respectively, only select further offers on the other market side from those that have just arrived. However, Gregg and Petrongolo (2005) concluded that the true (single) matching process is equivalent to one that is somewhere between the random matching approach and the stock-flow matching approach. Whereas random matching assumes a search process that consumes time to sample and assess all available and relevant (stocks of) offers from the other market side, the stock-flow matching approach is assumed to minimise the required time to check the stocks of the other market side to zero. These concepts offer me a good opportunity to discuss the robustness of the focussed efficiency parameter estimates on the basis of two different matching functions.

Therefore, the matches are determined, on the one hand, by the stocks of the unemployed and the inflows of vacancies and, on the other hand, by the stocks of vacancies and the inflows of the unemployed. Technically, the matching function in Eq. (1) is complemented by the inflows of the unemployed u and vacancies v with their matching elasticities β Uf and β Vf :
$$ M_{t}=A_{t}U_{t}^{\beta_{Us}}u_{t}^{\beta_{Uf}}V_{t}^{\beta_{Vs}}v_{t}^{\beta_{Vf}} $$
(6)
The model that considers the variation of the augmented productivity term with occupational labour markets b, compared with Eq. (2), is then modified to:
$$ M_{tb}=A_{tb}U_{tb}^{\beta_{Us}}u_{tb}^{\beta_{Uf}}V_{t}^{\beta_{Vs}}v_{tb}^{\beta_{Vf}} $$
(7)
Table 5 shows some descriptive statistics for the aggregated flows from the data set.
Table 5

(Additional) descriptive statistics

Measure

Monthly averages 2000–2011 (in 1000)

 

Mean

Minimum

Maximum

Standard deviation

Unemployment inflows u

616

400

1088

101

Registered vacancies inflows v

177

97

337

52

Source: Own calculation based on the administrative data from the statistics department of the Federal Employment Agency 2000–2011

The logarithm versions of the stock-flow models are equivalent to the regression Eqs. (3) and (4) for the random matching model complemented by parameters and variables of the logarithm of the flow measures:
$$ \log M_{ijt} = [Right side of Eq.~(3) or (4)] + \beta_{Uf} \log u_{ijt} + \beta_{Vf} \log v_{ijt} $$
(8)

Thus, the variables logu and logv are the logarithms of the unemployed and vacancy inflows whereas β Uf and β Vf denote the matching elasticities of the inflows of the unemployed and vacancies, respectively.

The results of the estimations of the stock-flow matching parameters can be found in Table 6. Compared with Table 3, the columns contain the results of the same specifications augmented with the inflow measures for registered vacancies and the unemployed. The graphic representation for the month fixed effects (FE 3) and year fixed effects (FE 4) can be found in Fig. 6. Overall, the results do not reveal fundamental differences with those that are based on the random matching approach.
Fig. 6

Monthly and yearly time fixed effects and 95 % confidence band. Source: Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency, own computations. Notes: Specifications from Table 6, left side FE 3, right side FE 4, based on the data set disaggregated by occupations and NUTS3 regions. The blue dots and the vertical red lines mark the point and 95 % interval estimates; the interval is very small in some cases. In the left panel, the dots are linked with a line to illustrate temporal development. Time fixed effects with effect coding (reference period is January 2000 for month or year 2000 for year fixed effects)

Table 6

Robustness check: fixed effects estimation results based on the stock-flow matching model and data set disaggregated by occupations and NUTS3 regions

 

Dependent variable: logM

 

FE 1

FE 2

FE 3

FE 4

β Us

0.543***

0.554***

0.565***

0.583***

 

(0.016)

(0.016)

(0.013)

(0.013)

β Uf

0.044***

0.047***

0.071***

0.049***

 

(0.014)

(0.014)

(0.009)

(0.011)

β Vs

0.036***

0.029***

0.020***

0.022***

 

(0.005)

(0.004)

(0.003)

(0.003)

β Vf

0.044***

0.044***

0.031***

0.035***

 

(0.007)

(0.007)

(0.004)

(0.004)

Year dummies, effect coded (reference year: 2000):

d 2001

   

−0.116***

    

(0.030)

d 2002

   

−0.141***

    

(0.026)

d 2003

   

−0.115***

    

(0.017)

d 2004

   

−0.109***

    

(0.019)

d 2005

   

−0.074***

    

(0.022)

d 2006

   

−0.023

    

(0.015)

d 2007

   

0.068***

    

(0.020)

d 2008

   

0.136***

    

(0.015)

d 2009

   

0.140***

    

(0.017)

d 2010

   

0.168***

    

(0.020)

d 2011

   

0.142***

    

(0.020)

γ

 

1.712***

1.400***

1.433***

  

(0.543)

(0.271)

(0.270)

a

−4.449***

−4.694***

−0.829**

−0.812*

 

(0.609)

(0.590)

(0.399)

(0.412)

Control variables

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Monthly time dummies

No

No

Yes

No

Quarter dummies

No

No

No

Yes

Observations

2,393,683

2,393,683

2,393,683

2,393,683

Number of groups

55,316

55,316

55,316

55,316

Within R-squared

0.241

0.245

0.309

0.279

Driscoll-Kraay standard errors in parentheses. Column FE 3 includes monthly time fixed effects with effect coding (reference period is January 2000), compared with Fig. 6, left panel. Control variables are the share of female workers, the shares of workers at different skill levels (‘vocational training’ and ‘academic degree,’ reference group is ‘without vocational training’) in each NUTS3 region and occupation and the average age by the population by NUTS3 regions. The estimated coefficients are provided on request

*** p <0.01, ** p <0.05, * p <0.1

The foregoing is also true for the regressions’ estimates without the business cycle variable, compared with columns 4 to 6 of Table 9 in the Appendix and the right panels of Figs. 9 and 10 in the ‘Further results’ in the Appendix. Again, a ‘crisis dip’ arises after excluding the business cycle variable, GDPcyc,FS(i),year(t), from the regression equation.

The results of the analysis for the occupational labour markets can be found in Table 7. The columns contain the results of specifications analogous to Table 4, augmented with the flow measures. Again, the results are quite similar to those based on the random matching approach.
Table 7

Robustness check: OLS estimation results based on stock-flow matching model and data set disaggregated by occupations and NUTS3 regions

 

Dependent variable: logM

 

OLS 1

OLS 2

OLS 3

OLS 4

β Us

0.441***

0.443***

0.478***

0.479***

 

(0.014)

(0.014)

(0.012)

(0.012)

β Uf

0.192***

0.194***

0.182***

0.180***

 

(0.012)

(0.012)

(0.010)

(0.010)

β Vs

0.043***

0.039***

0.043***

0.043***

 

(0.005)

(0.004)

(0.003)

(0.003)

β Vf

0.094***

0.093***

0.082***

0.083***

 

(0.008)

(0.007)

(0.006)

(0.005)

Year dummies, effect coded (reference year: 2000):

d 2001

  

-0.114***

-0.122***

   

(0.029)

(0.027)

d 2002

  

-0.122***

-0.129***

   

(0.025)

(0.024)

d 2003

  

-0.086***

-0.099***

   

(0.018)

(0.021)

d 2004

  

-0.078***

-0.080***

   

(0.020)

(0.022)

d 2005

  

-0.036

-0.035

   

(0.023)

(0.022)

d 2006

  

-0.004

-0.012

   

(0.015)

(0.016)

d 2007

  

0.057***

0.068***

   

(0.019)

(0.022)

d 2008

  

0.103***

0.117***

   

(0.016)

(0.019)

d 2009

  

0.123***

0.139***

   

(0.018)

(0.018)

d 2010

  

0.130***

0.134***

   

(0.019)

(0.018)

d 2011

  

0.096***

0.106***

   

(0.022)

(0.027)

Dummies for occupational categories, effect coded (reference: [0]/[1] AGR)

[02] EMB

  

-0.020**

-0.024**

   

(0.010)

(0.010)

[03] QMB

  

0.028**

0.026***

   

(0.011)

(0.007)

[04] TEC

  

-0.070***

-0.069***

   

(0.007)

(0.006)

[05] ING

  

-0.091***

-0.078***

   

(0.014)

(0.008)

[06] EDI

  

-0.097***

-0.100***

   

(0.008)

(0.007)

[07] QDI

  

0.063***

0.061***

   

(0.007)

(0.007)

[08] SEMI

  

0.080***

0.078***

   

(0.012)

(0.011)

[09] PROF

  

0.237***

0.246***

   

(0.014)

(0.011)

[10] EVB

  

-0.182***

-0.181***

   

(0.008)

(0.008)

[11] QVB

  

-0.031***

-0.032***

   

(0.008)

(0.008)

[12] MAN

  

0.015*

0.013*

   

(0.008)

(0.007)

γ

 

1.597***

1.610***

1.555***

  

(0.524)

(0.278)

(0.271)

a

-3.960***

-4.102***

-1.137**

-1.275***

 

(0.595)

(0.570)

(0.436)

(0.394)

Control variables

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Local area effects

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Occupational yearly interaction effects

No

No

No

Yes

Quarter dummies

No

No

Yes

Yes

Observations

2,393,683

2,393,683

2,393,683

2,393,683

R-squared

0.725

0.726

0.741

0.742

Driscoll-Kraay standard errors in parentheses. Column OLS 4 includes yearly time and occupational category interaction effects (reference year is 2000, reference category is ‘[01] AGR Agrarian and not assignable occupations’), all dummy variables are effect coded, compare ‘Effect coding’ in the Appendix. Control variables are the share of female workers, the shares of workers at different skill levels (‘vocational training’ and ‘academic degree,’ reference group is ‘without vocational training’) in each NUTS3 region and occupation, and the average age by the population by NUTS3 regions. The estimated coefficients are provided on request.

[01] AGR agrarian and not assignable occupations, [02] EMB simple manual occupations, [03] QMB qualified manual occupations, [04] TEC technicians, [05] ING engineers, [06] EDI simple service occupations, [07] QDI qualified service occupations, [08] SEMI semi professions, [09] PROF professions, [10] EVB simple business and administrative occupations, [11] QVB qualified business and administrative occupations, [12] MAN manager

*** p <0.01, ** p <0.05, * p <0.1

Only the yearly deviations from average augmented productivity are mainly less volatile in the stock-flow matching approach than in the random matching model. Thus, the main conclusions of the previous section are unaffected. Finally, column OLS 4 reports the results of the full specification, including the year- and occupational-specific interaction effects. Again, I do not report the results for the specification, including year- and occupational-specific interaction effects (OLS 4), but I graphically show the point and interval estimations in Figs. 7 and 8.
Fig. 7

Estimated sums of the yearly dummy and the yearly interaction effects and 95 % confidence band by occupational categories (part 1/2). Source: Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency, own computations. Notes: Graphs refer to column OLS 4 in Table 7, based on a data set disaggregated by occupations and NUTS3 regions. The blue dots and the vertical red lines mark the point and 95 % interval estimates

Fig. 8

Estimated sums of the yearly dummy and the yearly interaction effects and 95 % confidence band by occupational categories (part 2/2). Source: Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency, own computations. Notes: Graphs refer to column OLS 4 in Table 7, based on data set disaggregated by occupations and NUTS3 regions. The blue dots and the vertical red lines mark the point and 95 % interval estimates

Considering the results for the year- and occupational-specific interaction effects, there are only minor differences regarding the timing of the change and the further development of the matching efficiency.

Regarding the largest absolute changes of the yearly time fixed effects from year to year, Table 14 in ‘Further results’ in the Appendix shows hardly any differences compared with the results based on the random matching model (Table 13 in the Appendix) with the exception of the semi-professions and professions. For these occupational categories, the largest absolute changes in the yearly time fixed effects based on the stock-flow matching model was measured from 2004 to 2005 for the semi-professions and from 2008 to 2009 for the professions. However, regarding changes from 2004 to 2005, one should have in mind the data issues that were discussed in Section 3.

5.2 Aggregated data

Though it was necessary to account for cross-sectional dependence by computing Driscoll-Kraay standard errors, most of the estimates presented are highly significant. The reason for this result is the enormous variation in the data set the study is based on. From my knowledge, this study is the first to deliver such exact evidence. However, one shortcoming of such a detailed data is that the probability of measurement errors at the small local area level or occupational level increases. In aggregated data sets, these measurement errors could be ‘compensated’ for, and the prize are still higher standard errors. Because I am interested in the effects on partial labour markets, it is important to see whether the results would change after aggregating the data set. Therefore, I aggregated the data sets by NUTS3 regions over occupations and vice versa. As expected, the results show less precision, but the main conclusions remain stable. Compare Table 10 with Figs. 11 and 12 for the data set with NUTS3 regions as well as Table 11 with Figs. 13 and 14 for the data set with occupations, see ‘Further results’ in the Appendix.

6 Conclusions

In this paper, I present analyses of changes in the job matching productivity before, during, and after the German labour market reforms of 2003 to 2005, which are also known as the Hartz reforms, and an adjustment of unemployment benefits durations in 2006. Although one of the main objectives of the German labour market reforms was to improve the matching processes on the labour market, there are only a few studies that elucidate the direction and structure of the reform effects on job matching. Previous studies confirm positive effects, but there are different conclusions regarding the effects of the different reform stages. Furthermore, it was not known whether the reform effects covered the entire labour market or only parts of it. Another question is how the effects change during extreme economic situations like the financial crisis of 2008/2009.

The paper closes some of these gaps by estimating (unrestricted) macroeconomic matching function parameters on the basis of detailed, high-frequency and recent administrative panel data for the 2000–2011 period. To identify effects for occupational labour markets, I utilise an occupational category scheme that distinguishes between simple manual occupations, qualified manual occupations, technicians, engineers, simple service occupations, qualified service occupations, semi-professions, professions, simple business and administrative occupations, qualified business and administrative occupations and managers.

The results complement previous findings and show differences in the changes of matching productivity in different occupational labour markets. In general, five important new conclusions can be derived: (1) matching productivity increased during all reform stages, including Hartz IV; (2) even after controlling for the business cycle, further increases of the matching productivity were deteriorated in 2009, the year of the financial crisis; (3) the positive changes become smaller in recent years; (4) positive changes in the matching efficiency during and after the reform years are observable in all occupational labour markets, as suggested, in particular, by the results of the analysis for these occupational labour markets; (5) the results for the point estimates suggest differences in the development of the matching productivity between the occupational labour markets in recent years, but the changes from year to year are not significant.

The results complement studies that find that the German reforms had positive effects on the labour market. It can be stated that a more efficient job matching contributes to a more successful realisation of companies’ activity plans and, therefore, this higher efficiency should boost—rather than weaken—the standing of firms in their relevant markets.

7 Endnotes

1 Klinger and Rothe (2012) generated a dummy variable that was valued at zero before 2005 and unity after 2005. Hillmann (2009) assumed an exponentially growing reform effect during the first 12 months after Hartz IV was implemented.

2 German expression "Fördern und Fordern".

3 Thus, they estimated an averaged augmented productivity term before and after the reforms’ implementation.

4 Klassifizierung der Berufe 1988.

5 Further information can also be found in ‘Occupational labour markets’ in the Appendix.

6 Fahr and Sunde (2009) raised doubts that a macro evaluation of the last reform step in 2005 is hardly feasible within the framework that is used here and in other papers because it is not clear whether the further development in the matching efficiency after 2005 is an effect of the statistical break or due to changes in the matching efficiency. But the changes in the unemployment definitions went beyond a “statistical” break: before the last reform step in 2005, a certain part of persons capable to work were entitled to receive means tested social assistance (“Sozialhilfe für Erwerbsähige”). These persons were obliged to register as “job searchers” in their local agency but not as “unemployed” One could assume that the change of the ‘employment’ definition in 2005 changed also the support by the public placement officers for these persons who then received UB II. Though it is not possible to separately compare the efficiency of job search and matching with persons who received social assistance before and UB II after January 2005, it is of central interest of this and the other mentioned studies how the matching efficiency further developed after this institutional change.

7 Excluding these controls hardly change the main results, the estimations without controls are provided on request. Further details about the four control variables can be found in ‘Description and sources of the control variables’ in the Appendix.

8 Compare details about effect coding in ‘Effect coding’ in the Appendix.

9 See ‘Effect coding’ in the Appendix.

10 Details about the computation, the specifications and results are provided on request.

11 I use the procedure conceived by Hoechle (2007) with a (default) lag length up to which the residuals may be autocorrelated of 4 (m(T)=floor[4(T/100)2/9]=4,T=138).

12 In addition, the identification might also be difficult due to possible anticipation effects, which would be the case when firms or the unemployed changed their search decisions after the reform plans were published but before these plans were realised.

13 If I base this analysis on the assumption that the estimated average matching productivity (the constant in all models) for the 2000–2011 observation period is equivalent to long-term augmented productivity and should not change after varying the observation periods in the estimation, I might even conclude that the reform effects arise with a certain delay. However, this assumption can hardly be tested because it must be expected that a sample with fewer observation periods would reveal another value for the long-term augmented productivity and that massive short-term shocks on the labour market based on the Hartz reforms or the financial crisis would explain that more than ‘invalid’ data. This analysis implies that when there are substantial concerns about the value of the estimated augmented productivity, the observed positive or negative deviations from that productivity might be different based on the true value. However, the relative size of these time effects and a comparison of their year-to-year differences reveal that in 7 of 11 occupational categories, the highest positive change was from 2006 to 2007 (in addition to Figs. 4 and 5, which is shown in Table 13 in ‘Year-to-year differences’ in the Appendix). For the simple manual occupations (EMB) and the simple service occupations (EDI), this is 1 year earlier (2005/2006); for the professions (PROF), this is from 2003 to 2004; and for the qualified manual occupations (QMB), this is from 2002 to 2003.

8 Appendix

8.1 Occupational labour markets

Table 8

Assignment of Blossfelds occupational categories to the three-digit code of the German occupational classification scheme 1988 (KldB 88)

 

KldB 88—occupational orders

Occupational category

Code

Title

[01] AGR agrarian

11

Farmers

occupations

12

Winegrowers

 

21

Livestock farmer

 

22

Fish farmer

 

41

Mixed crop and livestock farm labourers

 

42

Livestock and dairy producers

 

44

Pet groomers, animal care workers and related occupations

 

51

Gardeners, horticultural and nursery growers

 

53

Florists

 

61

Forestry production managers, foresters and huntspersons

 

62

Forestry labourers

[02 EMB simple

71

Miners

manual occupations

72

Mining shot firers and blasters

 

81

Stone crushers

 

82

Earth, gravel and sand quarry workers

 

83

Gas and crude oil quarry workers

 

91

Mineral and stone processing plant operators

 

101

Stone splitters, cutters and carvers

 

102

Precious-stone workers, jewel preparers

 

111

Brickmakers and other stoneware makers

 

112

Cement and concrete block makers

 

121

Ceramics plant operators

 

131

Frit makers, glass vitrifiers

 

132

Hollow glassware makers

 

133

Flat glass makers

 

135

Glass cutters, grinders and refiners

 

141

Chemical products, plant and machine operators

 

143

Rubber products machine operators

 

151

Plastic products machine operators

 

161

Pulp and cellulose plant operators

 

162

Packaging makers

 

164

Other paper products machine operators

 

176

Hecto- and mimeographers

 

177

Printer’s hands

 

181

Wood-processing plant operators

 

182

Woodworking machine setters and setter operators,

  

and appropriate occupations

 

183

Wood products, brush and cork maker

 

184

Basketry weavers and wicker worker

 

191

Ore and metal furnace operators, metal melters

 

192

Rolling mill operators

 

193

Metal drawers and extruders

 

203

Casters of semi-finished products and other mould casters

 

211

Sheet metal pressers, drawer and puncher

 

212

Wire moulder, cable splicers

 

213

Other metal moulders non cutting deformation

 

222

Metal milling cutters

 

223

Metal planers

 

224

Metal borers

 

225

Metal grinders

 

226

Other metal-cutting occupations

 

231

Metal polishers

 

232

Engravers, chasers

 

233

Metal finishers

 

234

Galvanisers, metal colourers

 

235

Enamelers, zinc platers and other metal surface finishers

 

241

Welder, oxy-acetylene cutters

 

242

Solderers

 

243

Riveters

 

244

Metal bonders and other metal connectors

 

263

Pipe and tube fitters

 

301

Precious fitters otherwise undisclosed

 

313

Electric motor, transformer fitters

 

321

Electrical appliance and equipment assemblers

 

322

Metal, rubber, plastic, paperboard, textile and related products assemblers

 

323

Metal plant operators no further specification

 

332

Spoolers, twisters, rope makers

 

341

Weaving and knitting machine preparers

 

342

Weavers and weaving machine operators

 

343

Tufted textile, fur and leather product makers

 

344

Knitters and knitting machine operators

 

345

Felt and hat body makers

 

346

Textile braiders

 

352

Sewers and sewing machine operators

 

353

Lingerie tailors and sewers

 

354

Embroiderers

 

355

Hatters and cap makers

 

356

Sewer and sewing machine operators otherwise undisclosed

 

357

Other textile product makers

 

361

Textile dyer and dyeing machine operators

 

362

Textile bleaching, cleaning machine operators and other finishers

 

371

Tanners, catgut string makers and other leather preparing

  

machine operators

 

373

Shoemaking machine operators

 

375

Purse, hand bag and other fineleather products makers

 

376

Leather garment makers and other leather products machine operators

 

377

Leather glove makers

 

402

Meat- and sausage-processing machine operators

 

403

Fish-processing machine operators

 

412

Ready-made meal-, fruit- and vegetable-processing machine operators

 

424

Tobacco preparers, product makers

 

431

Dairy product machine operators, butter, lard and margarine makers

 

432

Grain- and spice-milling machine operators

 

433

Sugar production machine operators, chocolate, sweets and ice

  

cream makers

 

442

Steel fixers, concrete workers

 

452

Roofers

 

453

Scaffolders

 

461

Pavers

 

462

Road building experts

 

463

Track building experts

 

465

Land improvement, maintenance and hydraulic structure building experts

 

466

Well, duct and other civil engineering building experts

 

471

Earth-moving labourers

 

472

Building construction labourers and other construction and

  

maintenance labourers otherwise undisclosed

 

482

Insulators and proofers

 

486

Composition floor and terrazzo layers

 

504

Other wood product makers, boat, glider and

  

wooden sports equipment building experts

 

512

Goods painters and varnishers

 

513

Wood surface finishers, veneers

 

514

Glass, ceramics and related decorative painters, glass engravers and etchers

 

521

Products testers, sorters otherwise undisclosed

 

522

Product packagers, balers, wrappers, qualifiers and other loading agents

 

531

Labourers not further specified

 

543

Pump, compressor, assembly line, boring and other machines operators

 

544

Crane and hoist plant operators

 

545

Earth-moving and related plant operators

 

546

Construction plant operators

 

547

Machine maintenance operators, machinists’ assistants

 

548

Boiler persons, incinerators and related plant operators

 

549

Machine tool setters and setter operators no further specified

[03] QMB qualified

134

Gaffer

manual occupations

142

Chemical laboratory workers

 

144

Tyre vulcanisers

 

163

Bookbinding workers

 

171

Type setters, pre-press workers

 

173

Book printers, letterpress

 

174

Flat screen, gravure and intaglio printers

 

175

Special, silk screen printers

 

201

Moulders and core makers

 

202

Casters

 

221

Metal lathe operators

 

251

Steel-, black-, hammersmiths and forging press workers

 

252

Tank and container builders, coppersmiths and related occupations

 

261

Tinsmiths

 

262

Plumbers

 

270

Locksmiths and fitters, not further specified

 

271

Building fitters

 

272

Sheet metal worker, plastics fitters

 

273

Engine fitters

 

274

Plant and maintenance fitters

 

275

Steel construction fitters, steel ship builders

 

281

Motor vehicle repairers

 

282

Agricultural machinery repairers

 

283

Aircraft mechanics

 

284

Precision mechanics

 

285

Other mechanics

 

286

Watch-, clockmakers

 

291

Toolmakers, instrument mechanics

 

302

Precious metal smiths

 

305

Musical instrument makers

 

306

Doll, model makers, taxidermists

 

311

Electrical fitters, mechanics

 

312

Telecommunications mechanics, craftsmen

 

314

Electrical appliance fitters

 

315

Radio, sound equipment mechanics

 

331

Spinner, fibre preparer

 

351

Tailors and dressmakers

 

372

Shoemakers

 

374

Saddlers, truss makers and other coarse leather product makers

 

378

Pelt dressers, furriers and other fur product makers

 

391

Bakers and baked goods, cereal and chocolate product machine operators

 

392

Pastry cooks and confectionery makers

 

401

Butchers and stickers

 

411

Cooks

 

421

Wine coopers and other wine-processing operators

 

422

Brewers, maltsters and other brewer machine operators

 

423

Other beverage makers, coffee-processing machine operators,

  

tasters and graders

 

441

Bricklayers and masons

 

451

Carpenters

 

464

Shot firers and blasters except mining shot firers

 

481

Stuccoers, plasterers

 

483

Tile setters

 

484

Stove setters and air heating fitters

 

485

Glaziers

 

491

Interior decorators, carpet and parquet layers

 

492

Upholsterers, mattresses makers

 

501

Cabinetmakers, carpenters and joiners

 

502

Pattern and mould carpenters

 

503

Cartwrights, wheelwrights, coopers and tubbers

 

511

Construction painters, wallpaperers, varnishers

 

541

Power production plant operators

 

542

Winding, conveyor and ropeway machine operators

[04] TEC technicians

32

Agricultural engineers and advisors

 

52

Garden and landscape architects and administrators

 

303

Dental technicians

 

304

Ophthalmic opticians

 

601

Mechanical and automotive engineers

 

602

Electrical and electronics engineers

 

603

Architects, civil and structural engineers

 

604

Cartographers and survey engineers

 

605

Mining, metallurgy, foundry engineers

 

606

Other production engineers

 

607

Industrial and other operating engineers

 

611

Chemists, chemical engineers

 

612

Physicists, physics engineers, mathematicians

 

621

Mechanical engineering technicians

 

622

Electrical, electronics and telecommunications engineering technicians

 

623

Civil engineering technicians

 

624

Survey engineering technicians

 

625

Mining, metallurgy, foundry engineering technicians

 

626

Chemical and physical engineering technicians

 

627

Other production technicians

 

628

Industrial and other operating technicians

 

629

Forepersons and other operations managers

 

631

Agronomy, forestry and life science technicians

 

632

Physical and mathematical science technicians

 

633

Chemical science technicians

 

634

Photo laboratory technicians

 

635

Draftspersons

 

721

Navigators, nautical ships’ officers and pilots

 

722

Technical ship’s officers, engineers, technicians and machinists

 

726

Aircraft pilots, flight engineers and other air traffic occupations

 

733

Radio operators

 

857

Medical technical, laboratory, radiological assistants

 

883

Biologists, geographers, meteorologists and

  

other natural scientists, otherwise undisclosed

[06] EDI simple

685

Chemist’s assistants in pharmacies

service occupations

686

Filling station attendants

 

706

Cashiers, ticket agents, debt and vending machine money collectors and

  

ticket inspectors

 

713

Other brake, signal and switch operators, transport guides and

  

conductors, fleet managers

 

714

Car, taxi, bus, (heavy) truck and other motor vehicle drivers

 

715

Cabby

 

716

Construction and maintenance labourers: roads, dams, bridges and

  

similar constructions

 

723

Seagoing ships’ deck crews

 

724

Inland boatmen and related ships’ decks crews

 

725

Ferrymen, lockmasters, coastguards and other water traffic occupations

 

741

Stocks administrators and clerks

 

742

Lift, lifting-trucks and other materials handling equipment operators

 

743

Longshoremen, furniture removers

 

744

Stock, loading and other transport workers

 

791

Factories security offices, store, hotel and other detectives

 

792

Watchpersons, custodians, attendants and related workers

 

793

Door-, gatekeepers and caretakers

 

794

Menials, bellmen, ushers and groundkeepers

 

805

Disinfectors, morticians, meat and and other health inspectors

 

838

Clowns, magicians, acrobats, professional sportspersons,

  

mountain guides and models

 

911

Hoteliers, innkeepers, restaurateurs and management assistants in

  

hotels and restaurants

 

912

Waiters, waitresses, stewards, stewardesses and buspersons

 

913

Porters, bartenders and other hotel and restaurant attendants

 

923

Valets, chambermaids and other housekeeping attendants

 

931

Launderers and ironers

 

932

Textile cleaner, dyers, chemical purifiers

 

933

Dishwashers, room and domestic cleaners

 

934

Windows, frontages and buildings cleaners

 

935

Sweepers, streets and sewerages cleaners, dustmen and

  

other waste disposal workers

 

936

Car washers, vehicle cleaners, car and vehicle carers

 

937

Machinery, plant, tube and container cleaners

[07] QDI qualified

172

Stereotypers and electrotypers

service occupations

684

Chemists in drugstores

 

704

Finance, stock, trade, ship, real estate, insurance brokers

 

705

Landlords, hirers, agents, bookers, auctioneers

 

711

Locomotive engine, tram and subway drivers

 

712

Railway brake, signal and switch operators, shunters and

  

railway guards and conductors

 

801

Soldiers, border guards, police officers

 

802

Firefighters

 

803

Safety inspectors, trade controllers, gauging, and

  

environmental protection officers

 

804

Chimney sweepers

 

812

Law officers

 

814

Executory officers, prison guards

 

831

Composers, music directors and musicians

 

832

Film, stage and related directors, actors, singers and dancers

 

833

Sculptors, painters, graphic and related artists

 

834

Decorators, sign painters

 

835

Set designer, light board, image and sound recording engineers,

  

technicians and operators

 

836

Interior architects, visual merchandiser

 

837

Photographers, camera and retouching operators

 

851

Non-medical practitioners, psychotherapists

 

852

Masseurs, physiotherapists and health care professionals

 

854

Paramedics and nursing auxiliary workers

 

855

Dieticians, nutritionists and pharmacy technicians

 

856

Doctor’s receptionists and assistants

 

892

Nuns, friars and other religious associate professionals

 

893

Sextons, cantors and other religious assistants

 

901

Hairdressers, barbers, wigmakers and related workers

 

902

Beauticians, manicurists, pedicurists and related workers

 

921

Housekeepers and related workers

 

922

Energy and other consumer advisors

[08] SEMI semi

821

Authors, journalists, editors and announcers

professions

822

Interpreters, translators

 

823

Librarians, archivists, documentalists, curators, library and filing clerks

 

853

Nurses, midwifes, nursing and midwifery associate professionals

 

861

Social work, welfare, health care professionals and workers;

  

geriatric nurses

 

862

Housemasters, social pedagogue, deacons

 

863

Employment, vocational training, study, careers advisors

 

864

Kindergarten teachers, child care workers and paediatric nurses

 

873

Primary, secondary school, special education teachers and

  

related teaching professionals

 

874

Vocational, professional college teachers and related teaching

  

professionals

 

875

Art, music and voice teachers and related teaching professionals,

  

otherwise undisclosed

 

876

PE teachers, related teaching professionals, skiing and other

  

sports instructors

 

877

Driving, flying, hygienic and other instructors, otherwise undisclosed

[09] PROF professions

811

Judges and prosecutors

 

813

Lawyers, notaries, legal representatives, advisors and other

  

legal professionals

 

841

Medical doctors

 

842

Dentists

 

843

Veterinaries

 

844

Pharmacists

 

871

University, college professors and related teaching professionals

 

872

Grammar school teacher and related teaching professionals

 

881

Economists, psychologists, sociologists, political scientists, statisticians

 

882

Philologists, historians, philosophers and other humanities scientists,

  

otherwise undisclosed

 

891

Bishops, pastors, chaplains and other religious professionals

[10] EVB simple

682

Shop, stall and market salespersons and demonstrators

business and administrative

687

Commercial sales representatives and sales agents

occupations

732

Mail carriers, sorting clerks, porters and deliverers

 

734

Telephone switchboard operators

 

773

Cashiers and ticket clerks

 

782

Secretaries, stenographers and typists

 

783

Data entry operators

 

784

Scribes and other office hands

[11] QVB qualified

31

Agricultural production manager

business and administrative

681

Wholesaler, retail salespersons and buying agents

occupations

683

Publishers, management assistants in publishing and booksellers

 

691

Banking experts including tellers, finance clerks as well as finance

  

dealers and brokers

 

692

Building society experts including representatives as well as clerks

 

693

Health insurance experts including representatives as well as clerks,

  

not social security

 

694

Life, property insurance experts including representative as well as clerks

 

701

Logistics managers and transport clerks

 

702

Travel agency clerks, attendants, stewards, consultants, organisers

  

and guides

 

703

Advertising and public relations experts

 

771

Calculators, calculating and counting clerks

 

772

Bookkeepers

 

774

Computer scientists, equipment operators, computing and

  

data processing professionals

 

781

Office clerks, otherwise undisclosed

[12] MAN manager

751

Entrepreneurs, managing directors and division managers

 

752

Management personnel and other business consultants

 

753

Financial, tax accountants and accounting clerks

 

762

Senior and administrative state officials

 

763

Senior and administrative officials of humanitarian and

  

other special-interest organisations

[00] not assignable

982

Interns, volunteer with occupation remaining to be specified

 

983

Job-seekers with occupation remaining to be specified

 

991

Labourers not further specified

8.2 Description and sources of the control variables

The data that is the base for the time series of the share of female employees and the shares of the employees with the skill levels ‘without vocational training’, ‘vocational training’, and ‘academic degree’ on all employees stem from the employers statistics from the Federal Employment Agency. This data is measured for the whole observation period at the level of occupational orders (three-digit level of the German occupational classification scheme 1988, KldB 88 and NUTS3 regions). The basis are employees subject to social contributions without employees in vocational training. For the data about skill levels, employees without an information about skill levels are not considered.

The data that is the base for the time series of the average age of the whole population stems from the Federal Statistical Office. It is measured for each of the observed NUTS 3 regions, and it comes in age groups. To compute an average for the population, the middle values of each age group are weighted by the number of persons in this group and the mean of these values are computed. However, since the oldest age group has no upper bound, I calculated the middle value for this group based on data for the whole economy that stems also from the Federal Statistical Office.

The time series of the German real gross domestic product (in the model denoted as GDP cyc ) stem from the Federal Statistical Office (National accounts). German real gross domestic product by Federal states calculated is measured on annual basis. The cyclical component is computed by using the Hodrick-Prescott filter with a smoothing parameter of 6.25. German real gross domestic product for the whole economy is measured on a quarterly basis. The cyclical component is computed by using the Hodrick-Prescott filter with a smoothing parameter of 1600.

More details about these data and the computation procedures are provided by the author on request.

8.3 Effect coding

The time dummy variables, the occupational labour market dummy variables and the interaction variables that are used in the regression equation to analyse occupational and time-specific changes in matching productivity are effect coded. The advantage of effect coding is that the coefficients can be directly interpreted as deviations from the general, the time or the occupational specific intercept in the model. This intercept can be interpreted as the average overall, time-specific or occupational matching productivity.

Formally, the time dummy variable d y with y = [2001,…,2011] with reference year 2000 is coded as follows:
$$d_{y}= \left\{\begin{array}{ccc} -1 & \text{year}(t)=2000\\ 0 & \text{year}(t)\neq y\\ 1 & \text{year}(t)=y \end{array}\right. $$

The occupational labour market dummy variables d b with b=[2,…,12] with reference category ‘Agrarian and not assignable occupations’ (occupational category = 1) are coded as follows:

$$d_{b}= \left\{\begin{array}{ccc} -1 & \text{occupational category}(j)=1\\ 0 & \text{occupational category}(j)\neq b\\ 1 & \text{occupational category}(j)=b \end{array}\right. $$
To measure the occupational category specific reform effects, I use effect-coded interaction dummy variables with the occupational reference category ‘Agrarian and not assignable occupations’ and the reference year 2000. This interaction effect variable d b,y with y = [2001,…,2011] and b = [2,,12] is coded as follows:
$$d_{b,y}= \left\{\begin{array}{lll} -1 & \text{year}(t)=2000~ \text{and occupational category}(j)=1\\ 0 & \text{year}(t)\neq y~ \text{and}\\ & \text{occupational category}(j)\neq b\\ 1 & \text{year}(t)=y~ \text{and occupational category}(j)=b\\ \end{array}\right. $$

8.4 Further results

Table 9

Fixed effects estimation results based on data set disaggregated by occupations and NUTS3 regions, all regressions without business cycle variable

 

Dependent variable: logM

 

FE 1

FE 2

FE 3

FE 4

FE 5

FE 6

β Us

0.580***

0.623***

0.624***

0.543***

0.563***

0.582***

 

(0.013)

(0.009)

(0.010)

(0.016)

(0.013)

(0.014)

β Uf

   

0.044***

0.071***

0.049***

    

(0.014)

(0.009)

(0.011)

β Vs

0.065***

0.040***

0.045***

0.036***

0.021***

0.023***

 

(0.006)

(0.004)

(0.004)

(0.005)

(0.003)

(0.003)

β Vf

   

0.044***

0.030***

0.034***

    

(0.007)

(0.004)

(0.004)

Year dummies, effect coded (reference year: 2000):

d 2001

  

-0.098***

  

-0.098***

   

(0.031)

  

(0.030)

d 2002

  

-0.144***

  

-0.136***

   

(0.026)

  

(0.026)

d 2003

  

-0.134***

  

-0.127***

   

(0.017)

  

(0.017)

d 2004

  

-0.122***

  

-0.119***

   

(0.019)

  

(0.019)

d 2005

  

-0.103***

  

-0.096***

   

(0.022)

  

(0.022)

d 2006

  

-0.023*

  

-0.016

   

(0.014)

  

(0.015)

d 2007

  

0.098***

  

0.101***

   

(0.019)

  

(0.019)

d 2008

  

0.172***

  

0.167***

   

(0.013)

  

(0.013)

d 2009

  

0.087***

  

0.080***

   

(0.015)

  

(0.015)

d 2010

  

0.162***

  

0.151***

   

(0.021)

  

(0.020)

d 2011

  

0.159***

  

0.150***

   

(0.020)

  

(0.020)

a

-4.533***

-1.013**

-0.963**

-4.449***

-0.948**

-0.954**

 

(0.633)

(0.403)

(0.417)

(0.609)

(0.405)

(0.419)

Control variables

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Monthly time dummies

No

Yes

No

No

Yes

No

Quarter dummies

No

Yes

No

No

Yes

No

Observations

2,393,683

2,393,683

2,393,683

2,393,683

2,393,683

2,393,683

Number of groups

55,316

55,316

55,316

55,316

55,316

55,316

Within R-squared

0.236

0.304

0.274

0.241

0.309

0.278

Driscoll-Kraay standard errors in parentheses. Columns FE 2 and FE 5 include monthly time fixed effects with effect coding (reference period is January 2000), compare with Fig. 9 in the Appendix. Control variables are the share of female workers, the shares of workers at different skill levels (‘vocational training’ and ‘academic degree’, reference group is ‘without vocational training’) in each NUTS3 region and occupation, and the average age by the population by NUTS3 regions. The estimated coefficients are provided on request

*** p <0.01, ** p <0.05, * p <0.1

Fig. 9

Monthly time fixed effects and 95 % confidence band. Source: Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency, own computations. Notes: Specifications from Table 9 in the Appendix, left side FE 2, right side FE 5, based on data set disaggregated by occupations and NUTS3 regions, all regressions without business cycle variable. The blue dotsand the vertical red lines mark the point and 95 % interval estimates; the interval is very small in some cases. The dots are linked with a line to illustrate the temporal development. Monthly time fixed effects with effect coding (reference period is January 2000)

Fig. 10

Yearly time fixed effects and 95 % confidence band. Source: Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency, own computations. Notes: Specifications from Table 9 in the Appendix, left side FE 3, right side FE 6, based on a data set disaggregated by occupations and NUTS3 regions, all regressions without business cycle variable. The blue dots and the vertical red lines mark the point and 95 % interval estimates; the interval is very small in some cases. Yearly time fixed effects with effect coding (reference period is 2000)

Table 10

Fixed effects estimation results based on data set disaggregated by NUTS3 regions

 

Dependent variable: logM

 

FE 1

FE 2

FE 3

FE 4

FE 5

FE 6

FE 7

FE 8

β Us

0.691***

0.702***

0.601***

0.676***

0.832***

0.836***

0.516***

0.736***

 

(0.050)

(0.050)

(0.034)

(0.042)

(0.066)

(0.065)

(0.042)

(0.057)

β Uf

    

-0.238***

-0.230***

0.150***

-0.108**

     

(0.051)

(0.052)

(0.038)

(0.047)

β Vs

0.173***

0.158***

0.065***

0.113***

0.029

0.018

0.027***

0.031**

 

(0.031)

(0.031)

(0.013)

(0.020)

(0.026)

(0.026)

(0.010)

(0.014)

β Vf

    

0.201***

0.200***

0.076***

0.144***

     

(0.035)

(0.035)

(0.015)

(0.025)

Year dummies, effect coded (reference year: 2000):

d 2001

   

-0.138***

   

-0.187***

    

(0.048)

   

(0.045)

d 2002

   

-0.164***

   

-0.169***

    

(0.039)

   

(0.037)

d 2003

   

-0.097***

   

-0.096***

    

(0.029)

   

(0.029)

d 2004

   

-0.062**

   

-0.055*

    

(0.031)

   

(0.031)

d 2005

   

-0.024

   

-0.022

    

(0.036)

   

(0.033)

d 2006

   

-0.002

   

-0.005

    

(0.020)

   

(0.020)

d 2007

   

0.066**

   

0.072**

    

(0.031)

   

(0.030)

d 2008

   

0.131***

   

0.151***

    

(0.026)

   

(0.027)

d 2009

   

0.119***

   

0.166***

    

(0.032)

   

(0.031)

d 2010

   

0.164***

   

0.189***

    

(0.035)

   

(0.034)

d 2011

   

0.086**

   

0.102**

    

(0.041)

   

(0.040)

γ

 

1.274**

1.024**

1.041**

 

0.986*

1.135**

1.223**

  

(0.591)

(0.494)

(0.496)

 

(0.562)

(0.464)

(0.478)

a

-4.246***

-4.796***

0.164

-0.871

-5.534***

-5.960***

-0.440

-0.750

 

(1.234)

(1.246)

(0.758)

(0.803)

(1.098)

(1.080)

(0.728)

(0.794)

Control variables

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Monthly time dummies

No

No

Yes

No

No

No

Yes

No

Quarter dummies

No

No

No

Yes

No

No

No

Yes

Observations

55,371

55,371

55,371

55,371

55,371

55,371

55,371

55,371

Number of groups

402

402

402

402

402

402

402

402

Within R-squared

0.244

0.250

0.668

0.428

0.309

0.313

0.677

0.448

Driscoll-Kraay standard errors in parentheses. Columns FE 3 and FE 7 include monthly time fixed effects with effect coding (reference period is January 2000), compare with Fig. 11 in the Appendix. Control variables are the share of female workers, the shares of workers at different skill levels (‘vocational training’ and ‘academic degree’, reference group is ‘without vocational training’) in each NUTS3 region and occupation, and the average age by the population by NUTS3 regions. The estimated coefficients are provided on request

*** p <0.01, ** p <0.05, * p <0.1

Fig. 11

Monthly time fixed effects and 95 % confidence band. Source: Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency, own computations. Notes: Specifications from Table 10 in the Appendix, left side FE 3, right side FE 7, based on data set disaggregated by NUTS3 regions. The blue dots and the vertical red lines mark the point and 95 % interval estimates; the interval is very small in the some cases. The dots are linked with a line to illustrate temporal development. Monthly time fixed effects with effect coding (reference period is January 2000)

Fig. 12

Yearly time fixed effects and and 95 % confidence band. Source: Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency, own computations. Notes: Specifications from Table 10 in the Appendix, left side FE 4, right side FE 8, based on data set disaggregated by NUTS3 regions. The blue dots and the vertical red lines mark the point and 95 % interval estimates. Yearly time fixed effects with effect coding (reference period is 2000)

Table 11

Fixed effects estimation results based on data set disaggregated by occupations

 

Dependent variable: logM

 

FE 1

FE 2

FE 3

FE 4

FE 5

FE 6

FE 7

FE 8

β Us

0.867***

0.896***

0.929***

0.930***

0.925***

0.936***

0.838***

0.948***

 

(0.022)

(0.021)

(0.013)

(0.014)

(0.045)

(0.044)

(0.042)

(0.041)

β Uf

    

-0.083*

-0.065

0.086**

-0.035

     

(0.047)

(0.045)

(0.041)

(0.041)

β Vs

0.143***

0.124***

0.087***

0.098***

0.056***

0.041***

0.030***

0.033***

 

(0.015)

(0.014)

(0.008)

(0.008)

(0.017)

(0.014)

(0.007)

(0.009)

β Vf

    

0.112***

0.108***

0.072***

0.084***

     

(0.018)

(0.019)

(0.008)

(0.011)

Year dummies, effect coded (reference year: 2000):

d 2001

   

-0.343***

   

-0.365***

    

(0.045)

   

(0.044)

d 2002

   

-0.349***

   

-0.348***

    

(0.036)

   

(0.035)

d 2003

   

-0.260***

   

-0.266***

    

(0.027)

   

(0.029)

d 2004

   

-0.173***

   

-0.182***

    

(0.025)

   

(0.026)

d 2005

   

-0.086**

   

-0.097**

    

(0.038)

   

(0.039)

d 2006

   

-0.032*

   

-0.032

    

(0.019)

   

(0.020)

d 2007

   

0.144***

   

0.158***

    

(0.042)

   

(0.041)

d 2008

   

0.287***

   

0.306***

    

(0.049)

   

(0.051)

d 2009

   

0.346***

   

0.361***

    

(0.061)

   

(0.060)

d 2010

   

0.405***

   

0.417***

    

(0.026)

   

(0.028)

d 2011

   

0.349***

   

0.368***

    

(0.035)

   

(0.037)

γ

 

2.123***

 

1.804

 

1.956***

 

1.617

  

(0.640)

 

(1.376)

 

(0.639)

 

(1.354)

a

-11.549***

-12.287***

  

-12.761***

-13.268***

  
 

(1.183)

(1.263)

  

(1.174)

(1.241)

  

Control variables

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Monthly time dummies

No

No

Yes

No

No

No

Yes

No

Quarter dummies

No

No

No

Yes

No

No

No

Yes

Observations

42,053

42,053

42,053

42,053

42,053

42,053

42,053

42,053

Number of groups

327

327

327

327

327

327

327

327

Within R-squared

0.552

0.561

0.676

0.611

0.564

0.572

0.681

0.617

Driscoll-Kraay standard errors in parentheses. Columns FE 3 and FE 7 include monthly time fixed effects with effect coding (reference period is January 2000), compare with Fig. 13 in the Appendix. Due to collinearity, specifications FE 3 and FE 7 without GDP cyc,quarter(t) and the constant term a; FE 4 and FE 8 without the constant term. Control variables are the share of female workers, the shares of workers at different skill levels (‘vocational training’ and ‘academic degree’, reference group is ‘without vocational training’) in each NUTS3 region and occupation, and the average age by the population by NUTS3 regions. The estimated coefficients are provided on request

*** p <0.01, ** p <0.05, * p <0.1

Fig. 13

Monthly time fixed effects and 95 % confidence band. Source: Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency, own computations. Notes: Specifications from Table 11 in the Appendix, left side FE 3, right side FE 7, based on data set disaggregated by occupations. The blue dots and the vertical red lines mark the point and 95 % interval estimates; the interval is very small in some cases. The dots are linked with a line to illustrate the temporal development. Monthly time fixed effects with effect coding (reference period is January 2000)

Fig. 14

Yearly time fixed effects and 95 % confidence band. Source: Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency, own computations. Notes: Specifications from Table 11 in the Appendix, left side: FE 4, right side FE 8, based on data set disaggregated by occupations.The blue dots and the vertical red lines mark the point and 95 % interval estimates; the interval is very small in some cases. The dots are linked with a line to illustrate the temporal development. Monthly time fixed effects with effect coding (reference period is January 2000)

8.5 Predicted matching efficiencies

In the following Table 12 in the Appendix, I report predicted yearly values of the logarithm of (averages of) the augmented matching productivity A, referring to Eq. (1), and specifications without (Eq. 3) and with business cycle variable (Eq. 4, additional term in square brackets):
$$ \widehat{\log A_{\text{year}}}\equiv \overline{\widehat{\log A_{ijt}}}=\overline{\widehat{a}}+ \overline{\widehat{\mu_{ij}}} + \overline{\widehat{\mathbf{\theta X_{t}}}} [+\gamma \text{GDP}^{\overline{\widehat{{\phantom{00000}}}}}_{\mathrm{cyc,FS}(i),\text{year}(t)}] $$
(9)

Other frequencies, e.g. monthly values, or other aggregation levels, like occupational labour markets, are also computable and will be provided by the author on request.

Table 12

Predicted values for the augmented matching efficiency A (and logA) based on the estimates from specifications with and without the business cycle variable (BC)

 

Specification

Years

With BC variable

Without BC variable

 

FE 3 in Table 3

FE 2 in Table 9 in the Appendix

 

\(\widehat {A}\)

\({\log \widehat {A}}\)

\(\widehat {A}\)

\({\log \widehat {A}}\)

2000

0.409718215

-0.892285645

0.411119014

-0.888872564

2001

0.391941965

-0.936641514

0.393890768

-0.931681633

2002

0.374092937

-0.983251035

0.376081556

-0.977949262

2003

0.378048003

-0.972734094

0.380084157

-0.967362583

2004

0.382968634

-0.95980221

0.38472423

-0.955228508

2005

0.390673935

-0.93988198

0.39214623

-0.93612045

2006

0.4240987

-0.85778904

0.425949901

-0.853433549

2007

0.479338318

-0.735348642

0.481756747

-0.730315983

2008

0.515441298

-0.662731826

0.518508852

-0.656798184

2009

0.473781496

-0.747009039

0.47628665

-0.741735399

2010

0.512100458

-0.669234455

0.514599204

-0.664366901

2011

0.517209411

-0.65930742

0.519226968

-0.655414164

Source: Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency, own computations

8.6 Year-to-year differences

Table 13

Absolute year-to-year differences between the yearly time fixed effects sums from Figs. 4 and 5, based on the random matching model

Occupational category

2001/2002

2002/2003

2003/2004

2004/2005

2005/2006

2006/2007

2007/2008

2008/2009

2009/2010

2010/2011

[2]EMB

-0.005

0.006

0.004

0.023

0.140

0.075

0.103

0.017

0.047

-0.049

[3] QMB

-0.029

0.067

0.009

0.026

0.009

0.056

0.061

-0.013

0.049

-0.011

[4] TEC

-0.038

0.040

0.047

0.015

0.040

0.124

0.093

-0.029

0.025

-0.007

[5] ING

-0.029

0.042

0.079

0.075

0.019

0.128

0.103

0.000

0.003

0.016

[6] EDI

-0.043

0.031

0.032

0.008

0.099

0.056

0.073

0.037

0.025

-0.059

[7] QDI

-0.031

0.054

0.017

-0.038

-0.024

0.096

0.087

0.058

-0.034

-0.044

[8] SEMI

-0.011

0.031

0.063

0.073

-0.024

0.087

0.043

0.018

-0.038

-0.101

[9] PROF

0.004

0.064

0.098

0.016

-0.022

0.075

0.078

0.091

-0.054

-0.030

[10] EVB

-0.015

0.071

0.053

-0.007

0.051

0.099

0.096

0.018

-0.010

-0.066

[11] QVB

-0.046

0.052

0.051

0.012

-0.013

0.101

0.071

0.022

0.020

-0.053

[12] MAN

0.010

0.019

0.064

-0.001

0.039

0.149

0.071

0.048

-0.005

-0.034

Source: Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency, own computations. Bold printed values denote the maximal positive absolute changes of the time fixed effects.

[01] AGR agrarian and not assignable occupations, [02] EMB simple manual occupations, [03] QMB qualified manual occupations, [04] TEC technicians, [05] ING engineers, [06] EDI simple service occupations, [07] QDI qualified service occupations, [08] SEMI semi-professions, [09] PROF professions, [10] EVB simple business and administrative occupations, [11] QVB qualified business and administrative occupations, [12] MAN manager

Table 14

Absolute year-to-year differences between the yearly time fixed effects sums from Figs. 7 and 8, based on the stock-flow matching model

Occupational category

2001/2002

2002/2003

2003/2004

2004/2005

2005/2006

2006/2007

2007/2008

2008/2009

2009/2010

2010/2011

[2] EMB

0.022

0.009

-0.015

0.048

0.125

0.044

0.059

0.010

0.030

-0.041

[3] QMB

-0.002

0.064

-0.014

0.048

0.000

0.028

0.029

-0.013

0.040

-0.005

[4] TEC

-0.031

0.038

0.023

0.026

0.040

0.092

0.057

-0.035

0.035

0.000

[5] ING

-0.021

0.039

0.062

0.085

0.022

0.107

0.064

-0.012

0.018

0.014

[6] EDI

-0.018

0.025

0.017

0.040

0.098

0.038

0.036

0.027

0.012

-0.053

[7] QDI

-0.018

0.041

-0.003

-0.013

-0.015

0.078

0.049

0.047

-0.037

-0.037

[8] SEMI

0.004

0.015

0.039

0.084

-0.016

0.076

0.009

0.012

-0.038

-0.090

[9] PROF

0.017

0.051

0.077

0.025

-0.006

0.058

0.047

0.079

-0.043

-0.034

[10] EVB

-0.010

0.067

0.038

0.021

0.051

0.080

0.055

0.009

-0.011

-0.063

[11] QVB

-0.025

0.055

0.028

0.027

-0.019

0.078

0.027

0.016

0.026

-0.047

[12] MAN

0.018

0.025

0.045

0.005

0.034

0.125

0.034

0.041

0.013

-0.031

Source:Statistics of the Federal Employment Agency, own computations. Bold printed values denote the maximal positive absolute changes of the time fixed effects.

[01] AGR agrarian and not assignable occupations, [02] EMB simple manual occupations, [03] QMB qualified manual occupations, [04] TEC technicians, [05] ING engineers, [06] EDI simple service occupations, [07] QDI qualified service occupations, [08] SEMI semi-professions, [09] PROF professions, [10] EVB simple business and administrative occupations, [11] QVB qualified business and administrative occupations, [12] MAN manager

Declarations

Acknowledgements

I thank an anonymous referee, Axel Börsch-Supan, Ekkehard Ernst, Sabine Klinger, Florian Lehmer, Britta Matthes, Joachim Möller, Cornelius Peters and Enzo Weber for providing helpful comments and suggestions. I am also grateful for the feedback provided by various participants at the 20th Panel Data Conference, Tokyo, at a seminar of the IAB in Nuremberg, 5th Ifo Dresden Workshop on Labor Economics and Social Policy, at a Ph.D. seminar at the University of Regensburg, the OECD/IZA Employment Seminar, Paris. A special thank goes to Wolfgang Biersack and Franziska Kugler for the excellent research assistance. The usual disclaimer applies.

Responsible editor: Sara de la Rica

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Authors’ Affiliations

(1)
Institute for Employment Research

References

  1. Bieber, D, Hielscher V, Ochs P, Schwarz C, Vaut S (2005) Organisatorischer Umbau der Bundesagentur für Arbeit, Evaluation der Maßnahmen zur Umsetzung der Vorschläge der Hartz-Kommission, Arbeitspaket 2, Bericht, Berlin.
  2. Blossfeld, H-P (1983) Höherqualifizierung und Verdrängung - Konsequenzen der Bildungsexpansion in den siebziger Jahren. In: Haller M Müller W (eds)Beschäftigungssystem Im Gesellschaftlichen Wandel, 184–240.. Campus, Frankfurt/Main and New York.Google Scholar
  3. Bundesagentur für Arbeit (2015) Statistik der Arbeitslosen, Arbeitsuchenden und gemeldeten erwerbsfähigen Personen. Qualitätsbericht der BA (Version 4.0). Statistik der Bundesagentur für Arbeit. http://statistik.arbeitsagentur.de/Statischer-Content/Grundlagen/Qualitaetsberichte/Generische-Publikationen/Qualitaetsbericht-Statistik-Arbeitslose-Arbeitsuchende.
  4. Bundesagentur für Arbeit (2016) Statistik der gemeldeten Stellen. Qualitätsbericht der BA (Version 6.0). http://statistik.arbeitsagentur.de/Statischer-Content/Grundlagen/Qualitaetsberichte/Generische-Publikationen/Qualitaetsbericht-Statistik-Arbeitslose-Arbeitsuchende,
  5. Burda, MC, Hunt J (2011) What explains the German labor market miracle in the Great Recession?Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 273–319.
  6. Burda, MC, Wyplosz CA (1994) Gross worker and job flows in Europe. Eur Econ Rev 38(6): 1287–1315.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  7. Coles, MG, Smith E (1998) Marketplaces and matching. Int Econ Rev 39(1): 239.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  8. Coles, MG (1994) Understanding the Matching Function: The Role of Newspapers and Job Agencies. Discussion paper series / Centre for Economic Policy Research, Vol. no. 939. Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.Google Scholar
  9. Diamond, PA (1982a) Aggregate demand management in search equilibrium. J Polit Econ 90(5): 881–894.
  10. Diamond, PA (1982b) Wage determination and efficiency in search equilibrium. Rev Econ Stud 49(2): 217–227.
  11. Driscoll, J, Kraay A (1998) Consistent covariance matrix estimation with spatially dependent panel data. Rev Econ Stat 80(4): 549–560.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  12. Dustmann, C, Fitzenberger B, Schönberg U, Spitz-Oener A (2014) From sick man of europe to economic superstar: Germany’s resurgent economy. J Econ Perspect 28(1): 167–188.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  13. Engelhardt, A, Gehricke M, Jasiczek D, Kurtz B, Raub K, Zimmermann R (2014) Neuaufbereitung der Arbeitslosenstatistik - Revisionsbericht. Methodenbericht der Statistik der Bundesagentur für Arbeit: 25.
  14. Entorf, H (1998) Mismatch Explanations of European Unemployment: A Critical Evaluation. Springer, Heidelberg.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  15. Fahr, R, Sunde U (2004) Occupational job creation: patterns and implications. Oxf Econ Pap 56: 407–435.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  16. Fahr, R, Sunde U (2006) Spatial mobility and competition for jobs: Some theory and evidence for Western Germany. Reg Sci Urban Econ 36(6): 803–825.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  17. Fahr, R, Sunde U (2009) Did the Hartz reforms speed-up the matching process? A macro-evaluation using empirical matching functions. Ger Econ Rev 10(3): 284–316.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  18. Fitzenberger, B (2009) Nach der Reform ist vor der Reform? eine arbeitsökonomische Analyse ausgewählter Aspekte der Hartz-Reformen. In: Schulze GG (ed)Reformen Für Deutschland. Handelsblatt-Bücher, 21–48.. Schäffer-Poeschel, Stuttgart.Google Scholar
  19. Gartner, H, Fujita S (2014) A closer look at the German labor market ’miracle’. Bus Rev4: 16–24.Google Scholar
  20. Gregg, P, Petrongolo B (2005) Stock-flow matching and the performance of the labor market. Eur Econ Rev 49(8): 1987–2011.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  21. Hartmann, M, Reimer K (2010) Umstellung der Statistik der gemeldeten Arbeitsstellen. Methodenbericht der Statistik der Bundesagentur für Arbeit.
  22. Hartz, P, Bensel N, Fiedler J, Fischer H, Gasse P, Jann W, Kraljic P, Kungel-Weber I, Luft K, Schartau H, Schickler W, Schmid G, Tiefensee W, Voscherau E (2002) Moderne Dienstleistungen Am Arbeitsmarkt: Vorschläge der Kommission zum Abbau der Arbeitslosigkeit und zur Umstrukturierung der Bundesanstalt für Arbeit, Berlin.
  23. Hertweck, MS, Sigrist O (2012) The Aggregate Effects of the Hartz Reforms in Germany. Working Paper Series / Department of Economics, Vol. 2012-38. Bibliothek der Universität Konstanz, Konstanz.Google Scholar
  24. Hillmann, K (2009) Does the Hartz IV reform have an effect on matching efficiency in Germany? a stochastic frontier approach. Munich Personal RePEc Archive22295. http://hdl.handle.net/10419/37498.
  25. Hodrick, RJ, Prescott EC (1997) Postwar US business cycles: An empirical investigation. J Money Credit Bank 29(1): 1–16.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  26. Hoechle, D (2007) Robust standard errors for panel regressions with cross-sectional dependence. Stat J 7(3): 281–312.Google Scholar
  27. Jacobi, L, Kluve J (2007) Before and after the Hartz reforms: the performance of active labour market policy in Germany. J Labour Market Res 40(1): 45–64.Google Scholar
  28. Klinger, S, Rothe T (2012) The impact of labour market reforms and economic performance on the matching of the short-term and the long-term unemploymed. Scott J Polit Econ 59(1): 90–114.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  29. Klinger, S, Weber E (2014) Decomposing Beveridge curve dynamics by correlated unobserved components. University of Regensburg - Working Papers in Business, Economics and Management Information Systems480. http://epub.uni-regensburg.de/29927/1/KlingerWeber.pdf. Accessed 18 June 2014.
  30. Krause, MU, Uhlig H (2012) Transitions in the German labor market: Structure and crisis. J Monet Econ 59: 64–79.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  31. Krebs, T, Scheffel M (2013) Macroeconomic evaluation of labor market reform in Germany. IMF Econ Rev 61(4): 664–701.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  32. Krebs, T, Scheffel M (2014) Labor Market Reform and the Cost of Business Cycles vol. Annual Conference 2014 (Hamburg): Evidence-based Economic Policy. Verein für Socialpolitik / German Economic Association, Hamburg.Google Scholar
  33. Launov, A, Wälde K (2015) The employment effect of reforming a public employment agency. Eur Econ Rev 25: 140–164.Google Scholar
  34. Möller, J (2010) The German labor market response in the world recession – de-mystifying a miracle. J Labour Market Res 42(4): 325–336.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  35. Mortensen, DT (1982) Property rights and efficiency in mating, racing, and related games. The American Economic Review 72(5): 968–979.Google Scholar
  36. Ochel, W (2005) Hartz IV - welfare to work in Germany. CESifo DICE Report : Journal for Institutional Comparisons3(2): 18–25.Google Scholar
  37. Pesaran, MH (2004) General Diagnostic Tests for Cross Section Dependence in Panels. Working Paper Series / CESifo. CES, Munich.Google Scholar
  38. Petrongolo, B, Pissarides CA (2001) Looking into the black box: a survey of the matching function. J Econ LitXXXIX: 390–431.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  39. Pissarides, CA (1979) Job matchings with state employment agencies and random search. Econ J 89: 818–833.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  40. Pissarides, CA (1985) Short-run equilibrium dynamics of unemployment, vacancies,and real wages. Am Econ Rev 75(4): 676–690.Google Scholar
  41. Pissarides, CA (2000) Equilibrium Unemployment Theory. 2nd edn.. MIT Press, Cambridge and Mass.Google Scholar
  42. Ravn, MO, Uhlig H (2002) On adjusting the Hodrick-Prescott filter for the frequency of observations. Rev Econ Stat 84(2): 371–376.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  43. Rinne, U, Zimmermann KF (2012) Another economic miracle? The German labor market and the Great Recession. IZA J Labor Policy 1(1): 3.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  44. Rinne, U, Zimmermann KF (2013) Is Germany the North star of labour market policy?IMF Econ Rev 61(4): 702–729.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
  45. Stops, M, Mazzoni T (2010) Job matching on occupational labour markets. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik 230(3): 287–312.View ArticleGoogle Scholar

Copyright

© Stops. 2016